Chiang Chap 3. Transversality Conditions For Variable-Endpoint Problems
Chiang Chap 3. Transversality Conditions For Variable-Endpoint Problems
Chiang Chap 3. Transversality Conditions For Variable-Endpoint Problems
3
TRANSVERSALITY
CONDITI
ONS FOR VARIABLEENDP
OINT PROBLEMS
The Euler
calculus
equation-the
equation
differential
For
problems
two
given
But
to
the
if
to discretionary
be missing.
dynamic
externally
choice
definitize
initial
or
Such
will
monopolist
imposed
as an
and
be
of
in the
second-order
two arbi-trary
initial
terminal
constants.
points,
the
conditions
provide
sufficient
two
arbitrary
constants.
the
terminal
choice),
condition
normally
containing
with fixed
boundary
information
necessary
basic
varia-tions-is
of
then
the
point
is
variable
(subject
a boundary condition
case, for instance, if
the preceding
price at time
T and
chapter
can treat
faces
will
the
no
the PT
problem.
In
case,
that
longer
be
the boundary
condition
P(T)
available,
the
must
transversality
condition.
the transversality
of variable
and
In this chapter
conditions
we
PT will
filled
by
no
a
shall develop
to various
appropriate
types
For expository
TRANSVERSALITY
we
convenience,
=
be
termi-nal points.
THE GENERAL
CONDITION
3.1
void
shall
Once
is easily extended
initial point.
The Variable-Terminal-Point
objective is to
Maximize
Yy]
or
minimize
subject to
=A
y(0)
(A given)
~)= Y T
and
Y(
This differs
"free"
in the
optimal
although
time
sense that
process.
choice
version
and terminal
they have
It
is
to
be
~~f r
the problem
state
become
to the problem.
of
(T
y,
a part
understood
of
are
in
are now
of
the
that
relevant
the
necessary
conditions
for
an
we shall, as before, employ a perturbing curve
p(t), and use the variable
E
to generate neighboring
paths for comparison with the extremal. First, suppose
that T * is the known optimal terminal time. Then any
value of T in the immediate neighborhood
of T* can be
expressed as
To
develop
extremal,
where
represents
an
represents
arbitrarily
small
number,
can
and
AT
as a
be considered
function
prechosen
of
with derivative
E T(E)
7 rn
The
perturbing
same E
curve
the extremal
is used in conjunction
p(t) to generate
although
condition
p(0)
to
pass
condition-p(t)
paths of
y*(t):
However,
paths
with the
neighboring
the
0 [see
through
I
p(t)
curve must
(2.2)1
the
0-should
to force
fixed initial
now
still satisfy
the
point,
be dropped,
the
neighboring
the other
because
y,
is free. By
get
substituting
to
V(E) akin
function
(2.121,
(3.2),
the
upper
vary
with
function
of
by
but
limit
V[y],
since
of
integration
we
a
in
E:
~(c=
(3.5)
kT'"~[t, y*(t)
dt
~'(t
Y(t>
Our problem
to
is
is to optimize
E.
definite
by (2.111,
on
right
closely
resembles
of the rocess
the
one
encountered
arlier development
leading
the
in (2.13)
In fact, much
one
exception.
[Fyrp(t)];f in (2.16) does not vanish
value [Fy,p(t)],=,
p(T)
[F,,],=,p(T),
[ [
p(t)
Fy
in the present
since
we
- -F'!
dt
also write
Second term in (3.6)
problem,
have assumed
that
term in (3.6)
can
[Fit=, AT
[FY*],=,p(T
these
dV/ d
~=
0,
we
obtain
the
new
p(t)[Fy
- :FYr]
three terms
its
own
curve)
on
dt
[Ff]t=T~(T)
the left-hand
arbitrary
element:
[F]~=T
IT= 0
arbitrarily
on
chosen
perturbing
the perturbing
change
in T) in
of
of
Step ii
To
AyT-the
be
in
convenience.
initial
heights
the
done
represents
AZ
path
same
at t
perturbing
can
first
resulting
in
the
and
help
neighboring
Note
that
point
because
y,,
T because
curve.'
The
set
ZZ',
measures
also be altered
by
AZ'
the amount
This
curve
by perturbing
to
curves
the
one
for
share
the
p(T) # 0 by construction
magnitude
and
principal
problem.
equal
the two
p(0)
AT
of
two
3.1. The
of Fig.
while
the arbitrary
the
path obtained
~p(t ),
with
by
get rid of
it into terms
variable-terminal-point
with
y,
we
end,
changes
variables
can
this
p(T) by transforming
quantity
3.1
3.1
FIGURE
FIGURE
of
p(T),
the direct
But
the
by
change
in
inasmuch
EAT (= AT
of
shown
as
since
>
between
change
y, can
in
be approximated
Rearranging
terms
allows
by
Z to point
from point
this relation
Z" is
us to express
p(T) in
and
AyT
of
y,
AT:3
'~echnically,
be
labeled
the
because
justifiable
to-(3.9)-is
practice,
we are
portion
the
the
initially
result
the
that
condition,
path
3.1 should
in Fig.
simplicity.
discussion
This
is
as
anyway.
which,
the *)
is
leading
standard
should
extension
axis
for
this
T (without
interested
for that
as an
horizontal
omitting
in terms of
are
transversality
is stated
'~lthough
on
point
T*. We
enable
us
to plot
also
the
The perturbing
curve
is then
one as
in Fig.
AZ.
of
~hresult
e
even
in (3.8) is valid
if
3.1.
Step iii
This
condition,
only to
one
unlike
point
of the missing
of
the
we
condition
Euler
equation,
is
relevant
terminal
condition
in the present
problem.
Depending
or curve,
written
on
the exact
however,
in various
of the terminal
specification
the
general
specialized
(3.9)
condition
line
can
be
forms.
SPECIALIZED TRANSVERSALITY
CONDITIONS
3.2
In
this
we
section
terminal
points:
terminal
line,
consider
vertical
types
five
terminal
curve,
terminal
variable
of
line,
horizontal
truncated
horizontal
vertical
terminal
line.
vertical-terminal-line
1.5a, involves
term
can
fixed
either
This
gives
case, as
rise
which is sometimes
for
AT
Thus
since
sure
illustrated
referred
to
condition
as
Fig.
first
is arbitrary
and
make
is to have
to the transversality
in
the
0, and
Ay,
way to
out. But
in (3.9 )drops
take
the second
Fy r= 0 at
condition
For
the
Fig. 1.5b
Ay,
0 but
AT
is arbitrary.
drops
is arbitrary,
the only
sure
way to
might
,,
to
useful
y')
as a
current
so as to
build
profit
capital
stock
decision-say,
yl,--will
result
up
y, a
busines
tradeoff
any
between
is y',;
if
on
F(t,
y, y',).
rate
As to the
future profits,
we can convert
that into
(current
as
well
as
profi
future
decision. The
a unit of
means that
by the derivative
time t, with
of the investment
(or shadow)
is measured
resource
taking
profi
decision
y
net
investmen
specific
implication
us
let
where
decision
value
economic
ideas,
there exists
profit
an
function
profit-making
in the current
capital accumulation
zero
represents
. ,
give
represents
the
term vanish
equal to
condition is
be
in
have
term in (3.9
expression
F(t
operation,
we now
interpret
from
illustrated
interpretation
away
as
So the second
It
reversed;
automatically
for
case
horizontal-terminal-line
Fy,.This
capita
if
we
use
up)
terminal time
it will entail
negative
equal to
value
measure
of y',
decision
is -y',
Fyto.
Accordingly,
-Fyg.Thus, at t
rate y',
T, the value
implication
is F(t, y, y',)
of the
yb Fyg.The gen
eral expression
Now
in
select
(current
and
T,
future)
opportunities
profit
advantage
addition,
[
T such that
will, at t
capital
decision to invest
no
In other
profit.
should
have
of by the optimally
can
(3.10)-which
-FY,],=, = O-instructs
capital.
problem,
chosen
to maximize
in order
terminal time. In
by leaving
all the
fully taken
be writ-ten
any
In other words, in
overal
words,
equivalently
terminal
been
and accumulate
any
longer yield
ever
as
sacrifice
positive
free-terminal-state
in the interva
profit
that
up
all
accumulated.
Terminal Curve
With
terminal
1.5c, neither
neither
term
arbitrary
AyT
curve
nor
yT
AT
in (3.9)
= +(T),as
is
drops
So it is possible to eliminate
illustrated
assigned
a zero
value,
curve
Ay,
implies
that
in Fig.
Ay,
q S=AT.
is arbitrary,
F,vqS]t-TAT
we can
so
small
condition
two
cases,
which
in the terminal
point
(either
Unlike
unknown
the
last
involve
y,
or
single
TI, the
y,
purpose.
The transversality condition (3.12) only provides one; the
other is supplied by the equation y, = +(T 1.
case
terminal-curve
Truncated
Vertical
The usual
case
specidixes
(3.9) to
When
are
level
of
types of
the
is truncated-restricted
by
restriction
basic
there
are
values
both
take
ymi nis
= 0,
the terminal
a minimum permissible
y-the
optimal solution can have two possible
outcome: y,* > ymi nor y,* = ymin If y,* > ymin
is, it is nonbinding.
can
for this
Terminal Line
yT 2 ymi where
terminal
The
to determine both
needed
the line
condition
us
requires
reason
either
automatically
satisfied;
same as
for
admissible
above
is
and
is
(3.10):
this
is
that,
neighboring
below
sign.
that
condition
y,*,
under
paths
so
Therefore,
this
outcome,
with
terminal
that Ay,
the
= y, - yT*
only
way
to
only
2
y,*
admits
paths
means
arbitrary
that
E
condition
in
p(T )
dV / d
inequality
as
maximization
in
has
the
but
the
Fig
3.1)
that
its
curve
have
0 would
transversality
in the
first-order
changed
to
conditions.*
type
of
For
an
a
inequality
is
= T A ~~0
(3.14)
for~,*=~,
and (3.16),
we may
condition
for
(3.17)
[F~)],=,
5 0
YT* 2
write
the
transversality
Ymi
- ~rnln)[~Y']t=T=
[for maximization
to be
to
The nonnegativity
be
[Fy,]t=TsO
following
y,
completely
restricted
the
roots
hand,
values
should become
(3.16)
Combining
is
3.1 Ay,
in Fig
Kuhn-Tucker
problem
longer
perturbing
[F y l
]t
the other
terminal
no
is
must
O-
(3.15)
(YT*
as
= 1 in
means
~
=
Ay,
the
(3 .13)-which
condition
called
>
(E
turn
on
with
negative)
Assuming
terminal value
mean
that
or
(positive
nonnegative.
,
,
.
,
.
.
,
,
neigh-boring
This
= y,,,,
y,*.
of
Fy,= 0 at t
(3.13) is to have
satisfy
~oan
r
Chiang,
explanation
Fundamenta
of
of the Kuhn-Tucker
conditions, see Alpha C
Methods of Mathematical Economzcs, 3d ed
If the problem
is instead
to minimize
inequality
transversality
condition becomes
(3.17')
[FY*]t=T
2 0
YT*
V, then the
and the
2Ymin
-~rnin)[Fy#]~=
=0
(YT*
[for minimization
The tripartite
complicated,
on
below
hand,
then
range,
permissible
we
with
set
just
maximum
deadline.
similar
discussed.
following
y,*
[F,,],,,
yT* 2 ymin
solved. If y,*
y,
optimal
condition
= y,,,
Horizontal
terminal
permissible
The
to
and
the
the [Fy#1,=,
value. If
<
lies
fails to reach
treating
in
)or
(3.17
as
the problem
horizontal
restriction
yT*
the truncated
Truncated
The
we can try
other
complementary-slackness
(3.17')
one
restriction
the
the
zero on
the
seem
y,,,
but its
application
condition
condition
V]
of
analysis
the
By
Terminal Line
line
time
of
truncated
analogous
transversality
may
be
for
by
the
represents
completing
such
vertical
reasoning,
condition
truncated
T,,
where
situation
terminal
we
for
task-a
is
very
line
gust
prob-lem:
[F
(3.18)
(T
maximization
T,,)
V, the first
,,
- Y 'F ~~]I~0
[F- ytFY.],=, = 0
- T,,)
to
inequality
Fig.
terminal
T*
IT,,
V]
of
EXAMPLE
1 Find
between
the point
Referring
3.2,
curve
we
y(T)
see
that
to the shortest-distance
-T
this
is
Minimize
ny]= /*(I +
0
subject to
y(0)
and
y(T)
=2
distance
in Example
y12)1'2
dt
t.
problem
but otherwise
problem
[for
[F
[for minimization
is
(T*
similar
(3.18')
with
is to minimize
in (3.18) must
condition
-~~F~~]~~
T*IT,,,
LO
- y1FY,] =
V]
of
the problem
If
[F
it is
4 of
t
1
It has previously
integrand,
extremal,
FIGURE
y(0)
determine
transversality
=a t + b
(1
constants
1,
we can
and
readily
other
condition
y")1/2
can
(- 1
b.
determine
constant,
condition (3.12). Since
the
the transversality
(at t
straight-line
say,
y*
condition
equation yields
the Euler
3 2
that
a, we resort
we have
be written
b = 1.
to the
as
- yl)rl(l + yr2)-l"
Multiplying
through
by
(1
y'2)1/ 2and
simplifying
.,
we can
reduce
T) But
=a
the
this equation
extremal
at all values of
actually
y*(t)
As
shown
in Fig.
=t
3.2, the
1
extremal
,-
is
.
.
a
straight
Moreover
meets
the terminal
line
at the point
that
(
1;)
we note that the slopes of the terminal line
and the extremal are, respectively
1and
1 Thus the
two lines are orthogonal (perpendicular) to each other.
What the transversality
condition does in this case is to
line
EXAMPLE
FIGURE 3 3
with boundary
have
y(0)
conditions
we
free. Here
horizontal
1,
y, =
10, and T
terminal line
as
depicted
in Fig. 3.3.
The
this
general
problem
solution
the Euler
equation
been found to be
for
quadratic
1)
Since
c,
of
has previously
that condition
ty'
+ y'2+
so
that
F,,
becomes
ty'+y12 -yp(t
+ 2y')
(at t
+ 2y1
which
time.
the general
still
cannot
- T/2 +
knowing
y, = 10
we
is
c, =
make
use
of
negative
value,
c, =
we
and
However,
the information
solution,
setting
we
cl without
of
that
c, =
equation
T/2
T and
value
of
end
a zero
slope
Example
into
the
T/2
That
differentiate
set
value
specific
slope at the
that
that
10,
follows
the
.
,
.
,
=
0 at
y*'(t), then
result
we
(horizontal
a zero
condition, we
The
determine
find
y'
to have
this
to get
the value of
To
c2
meet
To
= 0.
c, = 0; it
y*'(T)
or
is required
solution
let
-y'2
extremal
terminal
and
to
reduces
is, the
an
condition
extremal
horizontal
condition,
at the
the extremal
terminal
point
the
requirement,
by
attains
condition
pre-sent example
share
a common
slope
terminal line at t = T.
in
required
indeed
the
in
translates
transversality
dictates
with
that
the
the
given
Application
Let
us now consider
as a problem
the
monopolist
variable
terminal
terminal
line
transversality
for
assign
P,
thus
in this discussion
parameters,
state
condition
Evans
with
model
P,,.
With
truncated,
specific
the
of
dynamic
is (3.17) For
otherwise
Model
the
appropriate
simplicity,
numerical
solution
vertical
we
values
expressions
C
[i.e., a
= &, p =
&Q2
0,y
+ 1000
=
1000]
needed
in the transversality
condition.
Since the postulated
parameter
values
the ch
and particular
rl,r,=rt0.12
= 14 ;
shall
to the
yield
will
(3.20)
= Ale0
P*(t)
+ A2e-0
12'
12'
14:
If
we
assume
further
to be
conditions
and
then, according
should,
the boundary
P,=15;
P,=11$
=2
A, and
A,
in the fixed-
terminal-point
problem,
(after
rounding):
A,
The
reader
constants
produce
can
into
A,
6.933
verify
(3.20
that
Now
adopt
the transversality
normalizing,
The
-9.933
substitution
P*(2)
condition
(3.171
to
two
errors)
15;
as required.
state PT
variable terminal
these
of
rounding
from
OF VARIATIONS
in (3.19) equal
expression
does (apart
solution
we
zero at
10. Using
set
first
the
2. Upon
P(T) term
here
refers
to the general
at t
=T =
of (3.20) evaluated
2. And the
at the
same
Thus, (3.21)
can
more
be rewritten
condition
obtained
as
governs
that
A, +A2
to Po
result
we
specifically
-3
=0
and equating
the
A, and A,
A,
giving
us
4.716
we
find that
the stipulated
fixed
P*(2)
restriction,
terminal
T
point
to
that
attain
the problem
inflation-unemploymen
inflation,
-7.716
The Inflation-Unemployment
The
It remains to check
the terminal speci-fication
(3.22)
A,
and
Tradeoff
t problem
requires
value
is s01ved.
in Sec.
Again
2.5
the expected
of
zero at
has
rate of
the
given
terminal
ask:
time
What will
as a
vertical
:
T(T
terminal
if
may
0. It
happen
be
the terminal
to
interesting
comes
condition
line instead?
the Euler
equation is
= 0 in the
requires
~(0=) >
C b y Mting
(3.24)
=T
a vertical terminal line at the given T
now must use the transversality condition
0,
With
A,
however,
we
[Fyr]t=T= 0.
form
In the tradeoff
+ ap"
the
(3.25)
(at t
F,,
e-Pt
T which
can
be satisfied
parentheses
can
is
if and only
zero.
if the expression
where
The
T(T) and
obtained
from
T'(T) expressions
the general
solution
in the
condition
as
are,
ffp"j
= --1+ ap2
of
course, to
~*(tand
)
its
be
derivative,
both
evaluated
at t
Using (3.231,
we can
(3.24) and
When
we
finally
find
(3.25")
are
solved
simultaneously,
A,
and A,:
These
can
what value of
solution? To
solution
see
this,
we
T*(T)
the given
the result
requirement-driving
to
zero at
from the
at t
be
T*(T)
In view
emerges
substitute
T The
loss function,
this
since
the
already
earlier
has
version
target
the
the
of
value
problem
n-
of
to the vertical-terminal-line
switch
set
in
at n-,
Sec.
2.5
0, the
EXERCISE
1 For
general
3.2
the
solution
functional
V[yl
j:(t2
to the
= clt
+ yt2)dt, the
+ c2 (see
Exercise 2.2,
Prob. 1).
(a) Find the extremal if the initial condition is y(0)
2, yT free.
change,
if
answer to
will the
the preceding
problem
the terminal
2, yT 2 3?
5, T free.
new
extremal. What
is the optimal
general
(a) For
solution
the functional
V[y]
to the
=1
T(y'2/t3) dt,
B
= c,t B
the
c2 (see Exercise
extremal(s)
and
the
if
the
initial
condition
is
y(0)
0,
terminal
condition is yT
(b) Sketch
= 3 - T.
curve
and
the extremal(s)
truncated
vertical terminal
on
line is based
>
0. Show
curve
same
terminal
employed
for
the
truncated
vertical
to derive
line
transversality
condition (3.18)
THREE GENERALIZATIONS
3.3
What
we
have learned
be generalized
A Variable
If
same
line of
reasoning
can
0 instead, the
use
<
emerge.
the
transversality
section
can
point
y(0)
transversality
terminal point
Initial Point
initial
condition
in three directions.
condition
is
no
longer
then
the
boundary
holds,
and
an
initial
conditions
be applied,
variable,
developed
mutatis
in
mutandis,
the
preceding
to the
case
of
variable
initial
discussion.
points,
If
points
there
variable,
no
is
has
problem
two
then
need
both
for
the
further
initial
and
transversality
conditions
have to be used to definitize the two
arbitrary constants that arise from the Euler equation.
so
functional,
appear
state variables
When several
in the objective
is
F(~,Y~,-.~,Y~,
into
[F - (y;FY;
transversality
(3.9) must
condition
(3.27)
' '
+~n'~y AT
~)
+[Fy{]t=TA~lT
+ "' +[Fy,']t=TA~nTO
It should
be clear
Given
has
term
that
n = 1.
a fixed
(3.27) with
terminal
AT
terminal
fixed
in (3.27)
represent
independently
Thus,
in
there
(3.27)
each
cannot
can
term
that
transversality
The
may
expect
be
cancel
all
the
the
determined
any
out
remains
will
another.
give
variable
that
rise
y,
remain,
expressions
arbitrary
presumption
one
of
terms
A
case
term in (3.27)
any
if
then AyJT
out. For
drops
we
special
0. Similarly,
value,
however,
(3.9) constitutes
that
to
quantities.
the terms
Consequently,
to
a separate
the
application
condition.
following
examples
illustrate
of (3.27)
by
2 is
z.
[F
EXAMPLE
both
The
2, with
1 Assume
,=,
hT
have
Eliminating
AT
the
first
term
individually
compare
should
Suppose
b3
Y,
and
and
in (3.27')
equal to
z,
AzT
and
zero, we
and
[c'lt=a
4 (T )
with (3.10).
satisfy
of
and
the restrictions
and
z=
AyT=$AT
yT
Ay,
conditions
E 2
for
[FY,],=,Ay,
0, but
[FY,It=, = 0
which the reader
denoted
condition
T is fixed, but
that
we
m
e
variables
transversality
free. Then
arbitrary.
state
the
general
- (yrF,,,+ z'F,.)]
[ Fzr],=,AzT
are
are
n =
when
and
and
*(T
For
dz,=#'AT
small AT,
74
PART
2. THE CALCULUS
OF VARIATIONS
Ay,
and Az,
we
in (3.27'),
obtain
emerges
condition
als
should
compare
curves y, =
conditions
z, =
4(T) and
y(0)
= yo
the terminal
and z(0)
to determine
equations
with (3.12).
condition,
* as
= z,, we now
well
as
have five
requires
the
high-order
(termi-nal)
modification.
derivatives
transversality
In
view
in economic
y,
F(t,
condition
of
the
..
again
rarity
applications,
condition
y',
we
for the
of
shall
case
The
means
new
symbol
the change
when
it is perturbed.
mean
the difference
at Z "
and
problem
between
the
Ay',
of
AZ
slope
F,,,
/T(y
the
remain
vary,
then the
T.
3 3
For the functional
the
must
0 at t
V[y]
of
path
2. If
term in (3.28)
slope is free to
EXERCISE
at
path
would
AZ"
of the
path
terminal
AyrT
the
of
condition,
slope
the slope
the
of
that
then
in this
terminal
In terms
slope
specifies
unchanged,
drops
the
appearing
in the
Euler
equation
is
y*(t)
= it2
+ yy' + +
y'
c,t
c,
(see
we
terminal
t
have
vertical
initial line at
0 and
vertical
line at
out
1 write
the
transversality
conditions,
and
use
them to definitize
the constants in the general solution.
2
Let
the
vertical
preceding
problem
be
new
extremal.
,
a
In
suppose
z, y',
z') dt,
= B, yT =
A, z(0)
constants).
/:~(t,y,
that y(0)
C, zT
(a) How
= A, z(0) = B,
y~ = C, and
y(0)
zT
condition(s).
suppose
that
we
have instead
are
constants).
(a) How
many
transversality
3.4
Consider
firm that
encountering
labor
varies
input
the
is
assumed
to
as
essence
well
on
the
of
magnitude
the
labor
Hamermesh."
discussed
in
a paper
by
of
OF
of
after
a cost
that
adjustment
L,
input
L,
0. The adjustment
entail
has to decide
as
has decided
a yet undetermined
a wage reduction at t =
to
Lo
from
of
condition(s)
toward
itself.
adjustment
This
L,
is
problem
The Problem
For simplicity,
in
3.4. The
Fig.
determinant
of
labor
(b
>
>
labor
over
input.
optimal
profit
also
during
but
but
as
also
from
the
to
value
rate
process
it must
an
we
n
t
optimal
have
T*
is
of
of
choose
changing
the
not
only
the
T*
for
time
both
the
feature
terminal
to note
should
at time
is T(L,)~-~ where
all
function.
C(L').
(a
is
integral),
definite
~,
value
and
profit
time
is that
the capitalized
the
Since
sole
to be
time is T(L)
the adjustment,
the problem
net
the
subsumed
in the profit
+ 0)
any
Inasmuch
by
illustrated
to be
have
time
LT,
completing
as
0,
taken
we
L is assumed
0 when L'
The problem
II
is
and demand
<
= b ~ + 'k
C(L')
0, and k
input
because
profit
aspects of production
The cost of adjusting
(3.29)
d L ) with a"(L)
of
in the post-T*
L,
.rr(L,),
and
T, too.
its present
So
the
rate
capitalized
'~aniel S. Hamermesh,
Adjustment
Costs,"
"Labor Demand
American Economic
1989,
pp.
674-689.
FIGURE 3 4
according
to the standard
.rr(L,,.)e-~~/~.The
capitalization
formula,
therefore
(3.30)
subject to
L(0)
and
L(T)=L,
Lo
(Lo given)
(LT>LOfree,T
free
If the last term in the functional
constant,
we
process,
emerge
the optimization
solution
were a
could ignore it in
path
would
because
the
same
either
z(T)-varies
choice
into
account.
earlier
the problem
way.
But
since
with
the
optimal
of
LT and
From
term-call
we must
it
explicitly
take
it
our
discussion
of
T,
that
Bolza,
of the problem
of
Mayer
and
we
Thus, by defining
~(t=)--p(L)e-0'
P
SO
that zf(t)
-.rr(L)
-.rr'(L)Lt
P
we can
e-~
term in (3.30)
as
(3.31')
Substitution
of (3.31')
in
combining
new
but equivalent
function
While
this
outside
affects
path,
of
functional
the
nq the
contains
still
integral,
that
term
is
ll value, but
optimal values of
L,
an extra
a constant.
term
So it
and T.
The Solution
To find the Euler equation,
we see
(2.189,
(3.33)
we get
the condition
Ltr-pL'+
-= o
p'(L)
2b
[Euler equation]
The
both
transversality
transversality
where
we
means
take
the
conditions
the
provide
determining
and (3.351,
the
the
of
equation, evaluated
obtain
necessary to
Lo
from
problem
must
and
is
satisfy
(3.11).'
The
means
(after
in the
optimal
the
at t
root
to
because
L,.
The
needed
and
path,
definitizing
as
well
as
T. In using (3.34)
general
solution
L,
for
is
two
it is understood
derivative
To
information
constants
the arbitrary
(3.10)
square
positive
increase
can
for
this
we
that
- L'FL,],=,
transversality
Lo,
in
free,
that
to
supposed
being
conditions
condition [Fc],,
simplification)
condition
LT and T
Both
twofold.
symbol refers
solution
of
the
to
Euler
T.
specific
quantitative
the profit
solution,
function
it
is
.rr(L)
Since
our
illustrate
terminal
primary
a case
purpose
with
both
of
the
citing
this example
terminal
state
and
is to
the
78
PART
CALCULUS
EXERCISE
the problem
(3.35), deduce
we
solution.
conditions
(3.34) and
the
of the optimal terminal
to Fig. 3.4.
an
increase in
an
increase in b
(c) Interpret
In the preceding
or
k affect
L,*?
your
result in (b). 2
of
problem,
function be
(b) At what
L,*.
a
can you say
L,*
THE
3.4
location
of
of Bolza,
1 (a) From
reference
OF VARIATIONS
peak?
about the location
in relation
(a) From
the location
of
the transversality
optimal
graph
of
condition
(3.35), deduce
the
terminal
time
T* with reference
to
the solution
path L*(t).
(b) How would
an
an
of
increase in b affect
T*?