Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C. 20554
Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C. 20554
In the Matter of )
)
Broadband Industry Practices ) WC Docket No. 07-52
)
)
EX PARTE FILING
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
The United States Department of Justice (“Department”)1 submits this ex parte filing to
respond to suggestions by some companies and individuals that the Federal Communications
traffic over the Internet—so-called “net neutrality” rules. The FCC should be highly skeptical of
calls to substitute special economic regulation of the Internet for free and open competition
enforced by the antitrust laws. Marketplace restrictions proposed by some proponents of “net
neutrality” could in fact prevent, rather than promote, optimal investment and innovation in the
Internet, with significant negative effects for the economy and consumers.
1
Through its antitrust enforcement and competition advocacy efforts, the Department has
substantial expertise in assessing competition and the effect of regulation with respect to the
Internet and “net neutrality”-related issues. The Department has undertaken extensive
examination of issues relating to Internet access and delivery services in connection with its
investigations of the AT&T/Bell South, SBC/AT&T, Verizon/MCI, MCI/WorldCom/Sprint, and
AT&T/MediaOne mergers. In AT&T/BellSouth, for example, the Department “investigated
whether the merger would create competitive problems in Internet services, including ‘net
neutrality’ concerns regarding the merged firm’s ability or incentive to favor its own Internet
content over that of its rivals.” Press Release, U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Statement by Assistant
Attorney General Thomas O. Barnett Regarding the Closing of the Investigation of AT&T’s
Acquisition of BellSouth at 3 (Oct. 11, 2006), available at
http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/press_releases/2006/218904.pdf.
The public policy objective here is clear: a thriving and dynamic Internet capable of
meeting the demands of consumers for fast and reliable access to a rich variety of content and
applications. Many commenters in this proceeding agree that the best way to achieve this
objective is through marketplace competition. Other commenters, however, have urged the FCC
undesirable differentiation in the provision of Internet services. Some of these proposals, for
example, could restrict broadband providers from offering different levels of quality of service at
varying costs to content and application providers in a manner that efficiently responds to market
demands. Other proposals would require interconnection, open access, and structural separation
of companies offering both Internet access services or transmission and content or applications
unnecessary governmental regulatory restraints, is the best way to foster innovation and
development of the Internet. Free market competition drives scarce resources to their fullest and
most efficient use, spurring businesses to invest in and sell as efficiently as possible the kinds
and quality of goods and services that consumers desire. Past experience has demonstrated that,
absent actual market failure, the operation of a free market is a far superior alternative to
regulatory restraints.
innovation, and diminish consumer welfare, and there is reason to believe that the kinds of broad
2
See, e.g., Comments of Google, In the Matter of Broadband Industry Practices, WC
Docket No. 07-52 (“Broadband Industry Practices NOI”), at 36 (June 15, 2007) (“Comments of
Google”) (encouraging the Commission to consider, among other things, interconnection and
open access requirements); Comments of Computer & Communications Industry Association,
Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 5-6 (June 15, 2007) (urging the FCC to adopt structural
separation rules).
2
marketplace restrictions proposed in the name of “neutrality” would do just that with respect to
the Internet. Congress passed the Telecommunications Act of 1996 to “promote competition and
services.4 Against this background, commenters proposing special regulation of the Internet
Based on the record in this proceeding to date, proponents of “net neutrality” regulation
have failed to show that a sufficient case exists for imposing the sorts of broad marketplace
restrictions that have been proposed. Moreover, the Department has grave concerns about the
potential negative consequences of such restrictions were they to be enacted. Given the dynamic
and evolving nature of the Internet, the Department finds that there are especially strong reasons
• The types of conduct that some proponents of regulation seek to prohibit—e.g., the
prioritization of certain content and content providers (such as streaming video and
other latency-sensitive content), offering of premium services and different levels of
quality of service, preferential treatment of certain content, and vertical integration—
in many instances actually may be procompetitive. A blanket prohibition on such
conduct would likely result in significant marketplace distortion. Even assuming that
a potential danger exists, the ambiguity of what conduct needs to be prohibited raises
3
Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56, 56 (preamble).
4
See, e.g., In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet
Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Review of
Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, CC
Docket No. 02-33, Report and Order and Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 20 F.C.C.R. 14,853,
14,896, paras. 1, 84 (2005) (removing common carrier regulations from “the dynamic and
evolving broadband Internet access marketplace”) (“Wireline Broadband Order”).
3
a real possibility that regulation would prohibit some conduct that is beneficial, while
failing to stop other conduct that may be harmful.
• Precluding broadband providers from charging fees for priority service could shift
the entire burden of implementing costly network expansions and improvements
onto consumers. Because the average consumer may be unwilling or unable to
pay significantly more for access to the Internet in order to ensure smooth
delivery to consumers demanding bandwidth-intensive and latency-sensitive
content, critical network expansion and improvement may be significantly
reduced or delayed.
• Mandating a single, uniform level of service for all content could limit the quality
and variety of services that are available to consumers and discourage investment
in new facilities. Services that are particularly vulnerable to delays in delivery or
other network problems may either not be offered or will be offered at a lower
level of quality than a competitive marketplace would have provided. In addition,
the resulting one-size-fits-all uniform level of service may deprive consumers of
the choice to pay for the quality they want—leaving some unhappy with the low
quality and others unhappy with the high price.
The Department urges the Commission to weigh carefully the potential negative
in this dynamic and evolving sector of the economy could perversely stifle innovation and
investment, reduce consumer choice, and increase prices to consumers. Anticompetitive conduct
about which the proponents of regulation are concerned will remain subject to the antitrust laws
and enforcement actions by government as well as private plaintiffs, and the Department will
4
I. THE GOVERNMENT SHOULD LIMIT REGULATION IN DYNAMIC
INDUSTRIES SUCH AS THE INTERNET
As a general matter, market forces, rather than regulatory restraints on competition, are
better at fostering innovation and investment, stimulating new products and services, reducing
costs, and expanding choice.5 Accordingly, regulation should be avoided except in those rare
instances of market failure (e.g., where competition cannot work because of a “natural
monopoly”) or where regulation is necessary to protect a clearly defined and compelling public
policy goal that cannot be achieved through competition. There is neither a sound theoretical nor
empirical basis for restricting broadband competition at this time. From a theoretical
perspective, differentiated products and pricing can provide consumers (and content providers) a
broader array of choices that meets service preferences more effectively and efficiently. Further,
such practices can enable greater investment that will speed innovation and development.
On the empirical side, despite the Commission’s request for evidence of harmful
suggesting that a problem exists. To the contrary, it appears that the Internet is flourishing
without the proposed sectoral regulation. Statistics evidence an explosion in Internet usage in
recent years due to new applications and increased broadband subscribership. According to press
accounts, in June 2006 alone 2.5 billion videos were watched on YouTube;6 by May 2007,
“hundreds of millions” of videos were being downloaded every day.7 Consumers increasingly
are utilizing the Internet for everything from shopping, to news and information. E-commerce
5
As reported by the Antitrust Modernization Commission, for example, “[n]umerous
studies of sectoral deregulation in the United States show that the unleashing of market forces
has greatly increased efficiency and provided substantial benefits to consumer welfare.”
Antitrust Modernization Comm’n, Report and Recommendations 334 & nn.9, 10 (Apr. 2007),
available at http://www.amc.gov/report_recommendation/amc_final_report.pdf.
6
YouTube Serves Up 100 Million Videos a Day Online, USA TODAY, July 16, 2006,
available at http://www.usatoday.com/tech/news/2006-07-16-youtube-views_x.htm?.
5
accounted for sales of $31 billion in the first quarter of 2007, an 18 percent increase from the
first quarter of 2006.8 Internet advertising produced $16.9 billion in revenues in 2006, a 35
The number of Internet subscribers also continues to grow, with reports indicating that
there were approximately 65 million new broadband subscribers worldwide from June 2006 to
May 2007.10 In 2000, there were 420 million online users worldwide, a number that increased to
1 billion in 2005 and is expected to double by 2010.11 In the United States, the FCC found that
high-speed (or broadband) lines increased by 26 percent during the first half of 2006, from 51.2
million to 64.6 million lines in service. Between June 2005 and June 2006, the Commission
found that high-speed lines increased by 52 percent (or 22.2 million lines).12
The increased usage and popularity of new services that are sensitive to delays in delivery
broadband providers have made, and continue to make, significant investments in Internet
7
See Comments of AT&T, Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 21 (June 15, 2007)
(citing Rob Hof, YouTube: 100 Million Videos a Day, BUSINESSWEEK, July 14, 2006, available at
http://www.businessweek.com/the_thread/techbeat/archives/2006/07/youtube_100_mil.html).
According to AT&T, some analysts project that video traffic will represent 80 percent of all
Internet traffic by 2010. Id.
8
Kristina Knight, Online Retailing Sees 18% Growth in U.S., BizReport, May 18, 2007,
available at http://www.bizreport.com/2007/05/online_retailing_sees_18_growth_in_us.html.
9
Internet Advertising Bureau, Internet Advertising Revenue Report 3 (May 2007),
available at http://www.iab.net/resources/adrevenue/pdf/IAB_PwC_2006_Final.pdf.
10
Michael Paxton & Elaine Potter, Global Broadband Subscriber Base to Nearly
Double, In-Stat, May 30, 2007 (“Global Broadband Subscriber Base”), available at
http://www.in-stat.com/press.asp?ID=2016&sku=IN0703510MBS.
11
See Thomas M. Lenard and Daniel B. Britton, The Digital Economy Fact Book 8 (8th
ed. 2006), available at http://www.pff.org/issues-pubs/books/factbook_2006.pdf.
12
FCC, High-Speed Services for Internet Access: Status as of June 30, 2006 1 (Jan.
2007), available at http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-270128A1.pdf
(“2006 FCC High-Speed Services Report”).
6
infrastructure to meet rising demand and reduce Internet congestion.14 The Commission’s
statistics report that the total number of broadband fiber lines increased from 40,627 in 2000 to
698,990 as of June 30, 2006,15 and the number of residential broadband fiber lines likewise
increased from 325 in 2000 to 442,027 fiber lines as of June 30, 2006.16
13
For example, reports indicate that YouTube consumes as much bandwidth as the entire
Internet consumed in 2000. See Jim Duffy, Don’t Expect Video to Exhaust Fiber Glut, Network
World (Feb. 15, 2007), available at
http://www.networkworld.com/newsletters/optical/2007/0219optical1.html. In addition,
according to Cisco, by 2010 “just 20 homes using the latest broadband technology to access
video content will generate enough traffic to equal the entire load on the Internet in 1995.” See
id.; see also Comments of Packet Management System Manufacturers, Broadband Industry
Practices NOI, at 1-2 (June 15, 2007).
14
For example, Verizon projects that it will spend nearly $23 billion to deploy its FiOS
service to 18 million customer premises by 2010. See Verizon Comments, Broadband Industry
Practices NOI, at 10 (June 15, 2007). AT&T reports that it has invested over $18 billion in
capital expenditures since 2004. AT&T, 2006 Annual Report 49 (2006), available at
http://www.att.com/Investor/ATT_Annual/downloads/ATT_2006_Annual_Report.pdf. AT&T
recently announced plans to invest approximately $500 million in fiber network upgrades to
deliver broadband services (including video) to customers in Georgia alone. See AT&T to Invest
$500 Million into Georgia Optical Infrastructure, Lightwave (May 31, 2007), available at http://
http://lw.pennnet.com/display_article/294094/13/ARTCL/none/XNEWS/AT&T-to-invest-$500-
million-into-Georgia-optical-infrastructure/. Comcast reports that it devoted over $11 billion to
capital expenditures in the last three years, including over $4 billion investment in 2006, of
which $320 million was devoted exclusively to upgrading its fiber-optic cable network.
Comcast, 2006 Annual Report 41 (2006), http://www.comcast.com/2006ar/annual2006.pdf.
Press Release, Comcast, Comcast Reports 2006 Results and Outlook for 2007 Announces 3-for-2
Stock Split 3, 10 (Feb. 1, 2007), available at http://media.corporate-
ir.net/media_files/irol/11/118591/Earnings_4Q06/4q06_release.pdf.
15
2006 FCC High-Speed Services Report tbl. 2.
16
Id. tbl. 3. Increases in the availability of fiber and DSL occurred as the FCC relaxed
wireline broadband regulation, see id. tbls. 1-3, which suggests that deregulation may be
correlated with increased investment. The Commission previously concluded that historic
regulation of the wireline broadband Internet access marketplace “constrain[ed] technological
advances and deter[red] broadband infrastructure investment by creating disincentives to the
deployment of facilities capable of providing innovative broadband Internet access services.”
Wireline Broadband Order, 20 F.C.C.R. at 14,865, para. ¶ 19.
7
In addition, several companies have developed services to provide faster delivery of
content and/or to avoid much of the congestion and delay on the public Internet.17 For example,
commercial content distribution networks, such as Akamai, Limelight Networks, and Internap
Network Services, operate thousands of servers throughout the world that cache content and
services to provide faster and more reliable access to specific Internet websites.18 Even though
these arrangements allow participating content and access providers to pay for a higher quality of
service, and thus create unequal treatment vis-à-vis other content providers, proponents of “net
neutrality” do not allege that such services need to be prohibited.19 In addition to these caching
services, the Department believes that there can be significant benefits in allowing broadband
providers to manage their networks and differentiate among some traffic on the Internet.20
17
Packets of traffic on the public Internet are processed on a “best efforts” basis, which
does not provide any guarantees regarding speed, delivery, service quality, or priority treatment
when the network is congested. When routers have more packets to process than capacity to do
so, the overflow packets are queued up for processing in the order they arrive, up to the router’s
physical capacity. Any additional packets beyond the router’s capacity are lost.
18
One of the largest content distribution networks, Akamai, reports that its services
“reduce the impact of traffic congestion, bandwidth constraints and capacity limitations” by
“accelerating and improving the delivery of content and applications over the Internet.” Akamai,
2006 Annual Report 1, 2 (2006), available at
http://www.akamai.com/dl/investors/akamai_annual_2006.pdf. According to Akamai, its servers
alone deliver 10-20 percent of all web traffic. Akamai, Facts & Figures 2, available at
http://www.akamai.com/html/about/facts_figures.html (last visited on July 16, 2007). Another
way in which a business service can obtain prioritized, more secure and reliable service is
through a virtual private network.
19
See, e.g., Comments of Google at 4 n.6.
20
Broadband providers also need the ability to prioritize Internet traffic in order to (1)
serve public safety officials better during emergencies, and (2) ensure the security of their
networks.
8
II. THE CASE FOR REGULATING THE INTERNET HAS NOT BEEN MADE, AND
REGULATORY RESTRAINTS CAN STIFLE INVESTMENT AND INNOVATION
TO THE DETRIMENT OF THE ECONOMY AND CONSUMERS
widespread problem. Rather, commenters advocating regulation cited only a few isolated
examples of problematic conduct, such as in Madison River, where a small, rural incumbent
local exchange carrier in North Carolina allegedly blocked the traffic of a competing VoIP
service. The FCC promptly addressed the issue and commenters submitted no evidence of any
such blocking or other harmful conduct since this 2005 incident. A few commenters cited
examples of alleged harmful behavior that occurred outside the United States, which are
irrelevant to the instant proceeding.21 Other commenters stated that there is not widespread
evidence of a problem.22
In contrast to the paucity of evidence of present harm to correct, there is reason to believe
that the type of regulatory restraints proposed by some commenters under the mantle of
“neutrality” could actually deter and delay investment and innovation, and result in less choice
and higher prices to consumers of Internet services. Proponents of “net neutrality” regulation do
not agree on a definition of what conduct should be prohibited, nor what networks would be
regulated (wireline and/or wireless), or even the extent to which pieces of the Internet need to be
21
See, e.g., Comments of the National Association of Telecommunications Officers and
Advisors, Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 8 (June 15, 2007) (citing a 2005 incident in
which a Canadian broadband provider, Telus, allegedly blocked access to the website of a Telus
union during a labor dispute between Telus and the union).
22
See Comments of Hands Off The Internet, Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 4
(June 15, 2007); Comments of the Media Institute, Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 3 (June
15, 2007); Comments of Fiber-to-the-Home Council, Broadband Industry Practices NOI, at 56
(June 15, 2007). Comments of Consumers for Cable Choice, Broadband Industry Practices NOI,
at 1 (June 15, 2007); Comments of the United States Internet Industry Association, Broadband
Industry Practices NOI, at 2 (June 15, 2007).
9
regulated (just the last-mile or the Internet backbone). The mere fact that a definition of “net
neutrality” remains elusive should give the Commission great pause before imposing regulation.
Without knowing what services and technologies will be introduced in the future, it will be
difficult to craft regulations that take into account the dynamic nature of the Internet. Indeed,
given the ambiguity surrounding what conduct regulatory proposals seek to prohibit, there is a
real possibility that regulation would prohibit some conduct that is beneficial, while failing to
As noted above, much of the conduct that some proponents of “net neutrality” regulation
are concerned about can be procompetitive. Differentiating service levels and pricing, for
example, is a common and often efficient way of allocating scarce resources and meeting
consumer preferences. The United States Postal Service, for example, allows consumers to send
packages with a variety of different delivery guarantees and speeds, from bulk mail to overnight
delivery. These differentiated products respond to market demand and expand consumer choice.
No one challenges the benefits to society of these differentiated products; nor does anyone
seriously propose that the United States Postal Service be banned from charging different fees
for next-day delivery than for bulk mailers. Whether or not the same type of differentiated
products and services will develop on the Internet should be determined by market forces, not
regulatory intervention.
providers should not charge content and application providers for faster and/or more reliable
service. Such a rule, however, could force consumers, regardless of their usage of broadband
services, to bear the costs of maintaining and upgrading broadband providers’ networks.23
23
Consumers also would likely face higher prices due to the added costs incurred by
providers to comply with regulations, such as monitoring and reporting requirements.
10
Several studies have noted that prohibiting broadband providers from charging content providers
directly would leave consumers shouldering a disproportionate share of the costs necessary to
upgrade network infrastructure. A recent paper by Benjamin E. Hermalin and Michael L. Katz
examines the relationships among consumers, broadband providers, and content providers, and
suggests that “net neutrality” regulation that requires broadband providers to offer the same
quality of service to everyone may be inefficient and reduce overall welfare.24 Other studies
have identified similar effects and have attempted to quantify the effect of proposed
regulations.25
Other “net neutrality” proposals could prohibit broadband providers from offering
differentiated quality of service. Such a rule, however, would eliminate choice and could deter
the use and development of new, latency-sensitive applications that require more reliable
delivery. A study by Robert Litan and Hal Singer concludes that without reliable low-latency
packet delivery, applications that demand a high quality of service, such as telemedicine, may
24
See Benjamin E. Hermalin & Michael L. Katz, The Economics of Product-Line
Restrictions With an Application to the Network Neutrality Debate 28 (AEI-Brookings Joint
Center for Regulatory Studies, Working Paper 07-02, 2007), available at http://www.aei-
brookings.com/admin/authorpdfs/page.php?id=1362&PHPSESSID=5db67c5b521ccdddb517c3d
be68ed2bb.
25
For example, Steven Pociask estimates that, if consumers bear the entire cost of
network upgrades through increases in broadband Internet access, this type of “net neutrality”
regulation will cause consumer surplus to fall $9.3 billion annually. See Steven B. Pociask, Net
Neutrality and the Effects on Consumers 24 (American Consumer Institute 2007), available at
http://www.theamericanconsumer.org/ACI%20NN%20Final.pdf. Although the study’s
approach depends on a number of key assumptions comparing market dynamics absent “net
neutrality” regulation (e.g., that the entire cost of network upgrades are borne by
content/application providers, which causes consumer prices for Internet access to fall and
demand to increase) with market dynamics with “net neutrality” regulation (e.g., that consumers
bear the entire cost of network upgrades, which causes consumer prices for Internet access to
increase, and demand to fall), the magnitude of the estimated loss in consumer surplus suggests
“net neutrality” regulation may not be in consumers’ interests.
11
not be viable.26 The Litan and Singer study examines online video gaming, another application
that demands high-quality packet delivery, and attempts to estimate the cost to society of “net
neutrality” regulation as to this application. The study estimates consumer surplus in the online
video gaming industry to be $195 million in 2006,27 and argues that “net neutrality” regulation
Finally, it may be efficient for content providers that demand higher quality of service to
bear the cost of upgrades necessary to support those services. Any regulation that prohibits this
type of pricing may leave broadband providers unable to raise the capital necessary to fund these
investments. Most significantly, regulation may reduce or deter investment in current and future
competitive alternatives for broadband access, such as wireless, fixed wireless/WiMAX, WiFi,
26
See Robert E. Litan & Hal J. Singer, Unintended Consequences of Net Neutrality
Regulation, J. Telecomm. & High Tech. L. (forthcoming 2007), available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=942043 (“Litan and Singer Study”). This
finding is consistent with comments submitted by users and providers of telemedicine, who fear
that regulations that prevent prioritization of packets could “threaten continued advances in
telemedicine.” See Comments of Provideaat 2, Broadband Industry Practices NOI (filed June
15, 2007). Providea is “a video communications and network integrator that supports health care
and ‘telemedicine’ applications across the nation.” Id. at 1; see also Comments of the
Association of Washington Public Hospital Districts at 1-2, Broadband Industry Practices NOI
(filed June 15, 2007) (urging against the enactment of “regulations that would stifle investment,
innovation and network intelligence” because such action would harm telemedicine).
27
Litan and Singer Study at 26.
12
III. CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, the Department urges the Commission to exercise caution
before initiating a notice of proposed rulemaking and adopting rules that would regulate this
dynamic sector.
Respectfully submitted,
Jeffrey Wilder
Assistant Chief, Competition Policy Section
Antitrust Division
September 6, 2007
13