Reaganomics: Olivier Jean Blanchard
Reaganomics: Olivier Jean Blanchard
Reaganomics: Olivier Jean Blanchard
Summary
MH*e»aiw,
Reaganomics
1. Introduction
In a country suffering from low growth, inflation and the Carter malaise,
the Reagan administration began with promises of a supply-side revo-
lution. Lower inflation, lower taxes and a smaller government were
going to boost productivity and growth. Thanks to the Laffer curve,
cuts in taxes were going to generate increased revenues and help balance
the budget.
The dreams did not last long. As it became clear that tax cuts would
lead to deficits rather than to cuts in spending or a balanced budget
supply-side boom, the strategy was abruptly changed. The centerpiece
of the policy became and has remained a political bet, the bet that cuts
in taxes would create, via deficits, the political pressure to reduce
government spending. It is this bet which, more than anything else,
distinguishes the Reagan conservative strategy from its European
counterparts and their strategy of fiscal austerity. Tax-cut induced
deficits, with their supply and demand-side effects have determined
the strength and the shape of the recovery; and they will affect the
future for a long time. If successful, they will lead to lower taxation
and lower spending. Successful or unsuccessful, they will have per-
manently modified the structure of taxation and will leave a legacy of
higher internal and external debt. Was it all worth it? That is the
question that this paper attempts to answer.
The dynamics of policy were set in motion during 1981-83. The
monetary contraction started under Carter was followed by large tax
cuts from 1981 to 1983, leading to the tight-money loose-fiscal mix
I thank Athanasios Orphanides for excellent research assistance, Jim Poterba for help and
comments and Cary Brown, Franco Modigliani, Larry Summers and Charles Wyplosz for dis-
cussions. I thank Data Research Inc. (DRI) for access to their data and forecasts, and NSF for
financial assistance.
18 Olivier Jean Blanchard
which has characterized the last six years. From 1981 to 1985, as inflation
decreased and deficits mounted, the economy went successively through
a recession and a sustained expansion. In 1985, a process to achieve
the required spending cuts was put in place tentatively, and in 1986
tax cuts were consolidated and modified through a tax reform that is
achieved in any of the years 1979 to 1982; credibility was clearly achieved
without strict adherence to any particular growth rate for M l , M2 or
M3. The Volcker disinflation was surely one of the most pragamatic of
recent disinflations.
By 1983, inflation was down to 4%, the recession was over and the
economy was growing. Deficits had swollen and monetary policy was
no longer center-stage, but it still played an important role. Table 1
shows that the Fed, faced with high fiscal deficits, decided to maintain
high real interest rates, and in the process to accept high and fluctuating
growth rates of the monetary aggregates. Real interest rates were, until
the end of 1985, high and roughly constant; they have since declined.
Neither the systematic failure to achieve monetary targets, nor the move
towards interest rate targets, nor even the decline in real interest rates
as activity slowed down in 1986 seem to have undermined the credibility
of the anti-inflation commitment of the Fed.
The rest of the action has been in fiscal policy. Table 2 gives data for
spending, taxes and deficits as a percentage of GNP for 1964, 1970
Reaganomics 21
Table 2. Government spending, receipts and deficits (% of GNP)
Fiscal Years 1964 1970 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986
Spending 18.8 20.0 22.0 22.8 24.0 25.0 23.7 24.4 24.6
1
Whenever they exist, I report numbers on a national income accounts basis. The government
and the budgetary process however use and report numbers on a 'unified budget' basis, which
uses slightly different accounting conventions. For example, asset sales are counted as revenues
in the unified budget accounts, but not in the national income accounts. Some of the numbers
below, such as CBO projections, or Gramm-Rudman targets, are 'unified budget' numbers.
2
Income from those accounts is untaxed as it accrues, and taxed as ordinary income when
withdrawn. There is a penalty for withdrawals before age 59.5.
22 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 3. Effects of the 1981-84 income tax cuts on marginal and average tax
rates (%)
Families with:
5 median income
with ERTA 16 6.7 13.4
without ERTA 21 8.7 15.5
median income
with ERTA 25 10.3 17.0
without ERTA 32 13.4 20.1
twice median income
with ERTA 38 16.7 20.8
without ERTA 49 21.7 25.8
(1)
£ = 1 0 % r=1.5%
structures 7.6 63.5 6.9 56.1 6.5 51.5
equipment 11.8 54.5 11.3 45.5 11.8 54.3
(2)
p=5%, r=3.75%
structures 10.6 47.8 9.6 38.8 9.3 35.5
equipment 13.9 30.7 13.2 21.0 14.1 32.9
(3)
p=5%, r=5%
structures 12.7 58.2 11.5 47.4 11.0 45.2
equipment 15.6 37.5 14.9 20.5 15.7 44.8
The stated purpose of the tax reform, signed in October 1986, was not
to reduce taxes further or to reduce deficits, but to reduce distortions.
The reform, not surprisingly, did not go as far as the initial proposals,
known as 'Treasury V and 'Treasury II'. In particular, it did not take
3
When the architects of the policy realized that tax cuts were going to lead to deficits is an
interesting question, but of more relevance to historians than to economists. Stockman's
autobiography (1986) suggests that he understood it very soon, as early as February 1981.
Reaganornics 25
the tax system in the direction of a consumption tax, as had initially
been considered, nor did it solve the problem of double taxation of
corporate earnings. But it was a wide-ranging reform, with effects on
both personal and corporate taxation.
4
In the original act, those cuts were to be made by the Comptroller General. After this provision
was declared unconstitutional in 1986, it was decided that the decisions would be made by a
joint committee of Congress.
Reaganomics 27
return to forecasts and guesses about the future course of deficits and
spending in Section 4.
From 1981 to 1986, the US economy went through three phases. The
first was dominated by monetary contraction, the second by fiscal
expansion. Anticipations of changes in the money-fiscal mix have
characterized the recent past. 5 The behavior of the main macroeconomic
variables is given in Table 5. Until 1982, the macroeconomy was domi-
nated by the effects of monetary policy. Deficits were still not large and
the main event was the increase in short real rates of interest. Once
financial markets believed that the Fed was committed to disinflation,
and thus to high real rates for some time, long real rates also increased.
Examination of the yield curve suggests that this happened in mid-1981
(see Blanchard, 1984). Distinguishing these credibility effects from
anticipations of high real rates due to anticipated higher deficits is not
easy, so that there is room for disagreement as to the precise timing.
By 1982 the increase in real interest rates had led to a sharp recession,
with unemployment reaching nearly 11 % by the end of the year. As
the increase in real interest rates was not fully matched by foreign
central banks, real actual and expected interest rate differentials also
led to a sharp dollar appreciation. The recession and the dollar appreci-
ation both contributed to the decrease in inflation, from 9.7% in 1981
to 3.8% in 1983.
By the end of 1982, budget deficits had become the dominant
macroeconomic force. Large deficits were strongly increasing aggregate
demand and putting pressure on interest rates. The policy of the Fed
was to only partially accommodate; the policy of foreign central banks
was to only partially respond to the US interest rates. The result was
an increase in US interest rates, a smaller increase in foreign interest
rates and further dollar appreciation. (See for example Blanchard and
Dornbusch; 1986; Feldstein, 1986). For the next three years, short and
5
The relation of monetary and fiscal policy to interest rates, exchange rates and activity is
remarkably well captured by the Mundell-Fleming model, spiced with expectational effects. See
for example the various essays in Dornbusch (1986).
28 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 5. Basic macroeconomic statistics
Unemployment rate (%) 7.0 7.5 9.5 9.5 7.4 7.1 7.0
long real rates remained close to their 1982 values. Dollar appreciation
and higher real interest rates were not enough to offset the increase in
aggregate demand and there was sustained growth starting in 1983.
Dollar appreciation and growth combined to turn a trade surplus of
$26b in 1982 into a trade deficit of $75b in 1985, and to increase the
current account deficit from $ l b in 1982 to $11 lb in 1985.
By 1985 it had become clear that a shift in the money-fiscal mix was
required and might indeed be forthcoming. Anticipations of a decrease
in deficits, and the assumption that the Fed would again partly
accommodate any fiscal contraction, this time by a decrease in interest
rates, led to (or at least coincided with) a dollar depreciation starting
in early 1985. By 1987 signs of an actual shift in the mix are more
apparent. As a result of Gramm-Rudman, deficits are expected to
decrease from their 1986 high. Real short and long rates have decreased
by 2-3%. Dollar depreciation has not yet translated into trade balance
improvement: the trade deficit for 1986 was $106b, and the current
account deficit was $142b.
Reaganomics 29
This overview is in many ways too cut and dried. Various pieces of
the puzzle do not fit well.6 Two of them are relevant here. The first is
the behavior of the dollar exchange rate. While its movements are
broadly consistent with economic theory, the magnitudes and the timing
of the changes are more difficult to explain. (For a review of dynamic
One question which was much debated in the early 1980s was whether
the cost of disinflation in terms of foregone output, the 'sacrifice ratio',
would be lower if disinflation were more credible. There is little question
that, despite its lack of adherence to target ranges, the commitment of
the Fed to disinflation, backed by the support of the administration,
had become credible by the end of 1981. 7 Did credibility decrease the
sacrifice ratio?
To answer this question, I concentrate on the behavior of the Phillips
curve during the period. It is clear that monetary contraction, to the
extent that it led to high interest rates, a large dollar appreciation, and
thus to a decrease in the relative price of imported goods, brought a
faster decrease in inflation than it would have in the absence of such
an appreciation. This effect has been emphasized by Buiter and Miller
(1983) in their analysis of the Thatcher disinflation. By looking only at
" And not everybody has the same reading of the evidence. Barro (1987), reviewing the same set
of events, concludes instead that there is no evidence against the 'Ricardian equivalence' proposi-
tion that tax cut-induced deficits have no effect on economic activity.
7
The credibility effect was dubbed the PATCO effect for the President's firing in 1981 of air
controllers belonging to the PATCO union when they refused to go back to work.
30 Olivier Jean Blanchard
the wage equation - rather than at the price and wage equations, or the
reduced form relation between inflation and unemployment - 1 exclude
this effect from consideration. I adopt a fairly standard specification of
the Phillips curve, relating quarterly wage inflation to price inflation
Deficits have clearly shaped the recovery. But before attributing the
recovery to fiscal policy, one would want to know what would have
happened if the US had followed a policy of fiscal orthodoxy as in
Europe. Would there have been a recovery and how would it have
differed? This is obviously an important question to answer. 8 Still, some
progress can be made by comparing this recovery with previous ones.
Table 7 presents the rate of growth of GNP, domestic spending and
its main components for the last four expansions. The current recovery
8
The main difficulty resides in the need to define what monetary policy would have been in the
absence of deficits. Blinder (1984) makes a courageous attempt to answer the question, using
three econometric models and comparing the behavior of the economy with and without the
fiscal changes. He assumes that the growth of M2 would have been the same. Doing his simulations
in 1982, Blinder however underestimated the size of the coming deficits and his simulations end
up shedding little light on the question at hand.
Reaganomics 31
Table 6. The changing cost of disinflation
Forecast errors
1980Q1 0.15 1983Q1 -1.11
Q2 0.09 Q2 -2.16
Q3 0.01 Q3 -2.70
Q4 0.72 Q4 -1.38
1981Q1 0.32 1984Q1 -3.07
Q2 -1.61 Q2 -2.74
Q3 -0.71 Q3 -2.53
Q4 -1.51 Q4 -2.35
1982Q1 -0.64 1985Q1 -1.90
Q2 -1.63 Q2 -2.09
Q3 -0.12 Q3 -2.55
Q4 -2.08 Q4 -1.78
has not ended yet (DRI does not currently predict a recession for the
next three years: the table also reports the DRI forecasts for 1987-89,
and what they would imply for the 1983-89 recovery).
Through 1986 the rate of growth of output has not been higher than
in previous recoveries. The rate of growth of domestic spending has
exceeded the rate of growth of GNP, hence the deterioration in the
trade balance, but it is not particularly high in comparison to previous
recoveries. The comparison with the long expansion of the 1960s must
take into account the fact that trend growth was higher then than now.
The recovery has not been abnormally strong by historical standards.
The other components of spending grew at rates surprisingly similar
to those of previous recoveries. In particular, investment, both
32 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 7. Comparing recoveries
% annual change in
State
Non- and
Sources: Historical Statistics, Department of commerce, peak and trough dates from NBER business cycle dating.
Note: *DRI forecasts, February 1987.
residential and non-residential, has grown at the same rate during this
tight-money loose-fiscal recovery as during previous ones, so that the
effects of higher real interest rates must have been offset by other
factors. One factor is the decrease in corporate taxation, although from
the numbers in the previous section, it is not clear that it has fully offset
the effects of higher interest rates.
Given the fact that GNP growth has not been abnormally strong, one
is tempted to conclude that the recovery would not have been much
weaker had fiscal policy been tighter. Indeed, there is no reason to
doubt that there exists some rate of growth of money which could have
decreased real interest rates sufficiently to achieve the same growth in
output, with the accompanying depreciation producing both a smaller
trade deficit and inflationary pressures. But there are good reasons to
doubt that such a monetary policy would have been adopted. Table 1
earlier showed that growth rates of money have been high. More
expansionary monetary policy would have required even higher growth
rates, and it is far from clear that after a successful disinflation the Fed
would have been ready to accept such rates. The experience of Europe
must be relevant here. After disinflation, European central banks have
been very reluctant to expand monetary aggregates; and in the absence
of fiscal and monetary expansion, European economies have not had
a recovery. The European experience makes a strong case for the
proposition that, without demand expansion, forces which lead to
recovery and a return to full employment are slow or simply non-
existent.
To summarize, disinflation was less costly than would have been
predicted. The recovery, while not exceptionally strong, must be partly
credited to the fiscal expansion. Apart from the excess of spending over
Reaganomics 33
output, the shape of the recovery has not been very different from
previous ones. In particular, investment has not suffered from the
money-fiscal mix.
The political bet has not yet been won: the reduction in taxes has not
yet led to drastic cuts in overall spending; thus one must rely on guesses
and forecasts as to what will happen over the next few years.
Table 8 gives DRI forecasts, as of February 1987, for spending and
taxes over the next three fiscal years. DRI does not expect that the
Gramm-Rudman targets will be met and assumes that, under some
guise, they will be revised upwards. This assessment is based on the
fact that the (non-binding) targets for fiscal year 1987 were exceeded
by $45b, and on the assessment that the budget presented by the
administration for fiscal year 1988, which formally satisfies the Gramm-
Rudman target, is politically infeasible. DRI also assumes that, because
of the proximity of the last tax reform and the next presidential election,
there will be no major tax increase. Nevertheless, they forecast a steady
decrease in deficits through reduced spending. Official deficits decrease
from 4.8% of GNP in 1986 to 3.1% in 1989, implying a decrease in
inflation-adjusted deficits from 3.8% in 1986 to 1.8% in 1989. An
inflation-adjusted deficit of 1.8% in 1989, together with a DRI forecast
of GNP growth of 2%, implies that the debt/GNP ratio will still be
growing at approximately 1 % per year by the end of the decade.
How much confidence should we have in these forecasts? Table 9
provides indirect evidence by presenting the evolution of projections
and forecasts over time since mid-1985. One can see how quickly
projections have changed. Congressional Budget Office projections of
the 1990 deficit which were $285b in August 1985, decreased to $97b
by August 1986 and increased again to $134b by January 1987. 9 Private
forecasts have fluctuated, although less widely: DRI has revised upwards
its estimates of future deficits over the last 9 months.
Assuming that by 1989 no further cuts in spending are politically
feasible and the budget is balanced, then or later, by a tax increase,
what will have been the results of the policy on spending? Table 8
suggests two conclusions. First, non-interest government spending as a
share of GNP will be the same in 1989 as it was in 1980. This may not
look like much of an achievement, but it is in fact a change from the
trend of increasing spending in the 1960s and 1970s (see numbers for
9
As explained above, CBO projections are not forecasts of fiscal policy, but rather projections
based on current legislation and CBO's forecasts of economic variables.
34 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 8. Forecasts 1987-89: spending, receipts and deficits (% of GNP)
1964 and 1970 in Table 2). If one assumes that, in the absence of
Reagan, the trend would have remained the same, non-interest spend-
ing will be approximately 1 to 2% lower as a share of GNP. Second,
the composition of spending will have substantially changed as well.
Defense spending, which had decreased by 2.5% per year through the
1970s, has grown by more than 6% per year between 1980 and 1986,
so that its share in GNP has increased from 5.1% to 6.5%. DRI however
expects some of the main spending cuts in the future to come from
defense, and its share to decrease to 6.2% by 1989. Transfers, which
had increased at 6.5% per year through the 1970s, have grown instead
at 3.5% between 1980 and 1986. By 1989, their share in GNP will be
the same as it was in 1981, a clear change in trend. Also, many programs
have been modified in important ways, for example the rules of health
care reimbursement. Other transfer programs have not changed: for
example the administration has been unable or unwilling to implement
major changes in farm policy so that payments to farmers have increased
from $8b in 1980 to $25b in 1986 as a result both of programs put in
place in the late 1970s and of various events of the 1980s (good crops,
bad export markets). Finally, non-defense purchases have decreased.
For example spending on education has decreased from $3lb in 1980
to $28b in 1986, and spending on energy has decreased from $1 lb in
1980 to $5b in 1986.
Reaganomics 35
Table 9. Projections, forecasts and dreams: future deficits (billion US dollars)
CBO August 1985 Baseline projections 212 229 243 264 285
Source: CBO: Baseline projections (various issues), Congressional Budget Office; DRI
Economic Review, various issues.
Note: Data on a unified budget basis.
There is thus little question that, even if deficits are ultimately elimi-
nated by an increase in taxation, both the level and the composition of
government spending will be different as a result of the actions of the
Reagan administration. In addition to changes in spending, deregula-
tion will also have modified parts of the private economy. In large part,
deregulation was started in the late 1970s before Reagan: deregulation
of the airline industry began in 1978 and was completed in 1985,
deregulation of the trucking industry started in 1980. A few new
programs were started after 1981, such as natural gas deregulation and
limited deregulation of financial institutions. Contrary to European
conservative experiments, there has been little privatization, as there
was little to privatize. The sale of Conrail, in the first Gramm-Rudman
compromise, was at least as much a way of closing the reported deficit
through the sale of assets as a way of improving the efficiency of the
railroad system.
While non-interest spending will be lower than it would have been,
the same is not obviously true for total spending. One of the effects of
the long sequence of deficits will have been to increase the level of debt,
and thus future taxes required to pay the interest on the debt. This is
one of the long-run effects of deficits, to which I now turn.
4 . 1 . T h e transition problem
dollar depreciation, the trade deficit has not yet improved. This has
led some (Baldwin and Krugman, 1986) to argue that the large appreci-
ation has led to the loss of markets for US firms, a loss which, to be
undone, will require a large depreciation. It is traditionally expected
that, when the exchange rate returns to its initial value, the economy
returns to the same trade position; the Baldwin-Krugman analysis
implies that in this case the US would still face a trade deficit. Recent
empirical work by Krugman (1987) fails however to find such effects
in the data (at least until mid-1986) and leads him to conclude that the
lack of improvement is due to the traditional J-curve dynamics and a
secular trend decrease of the real exchange rate needed to balance the
current account. The other related uncertainty concerns the behavior
of the Fed: will it be willing to move real interest rates sufficiently, for
example if a large reduction in interest rates is required to achieve the
required depreciation?
What these forecasts suggest is that both external and internal deficits
will be brought under control slowly, without any drastic effect on the
economy. Some of the worst fears which have been expressed about
deficits and debt are clearly unfounded. There is for example little
likelihood that deficits will require repudiation or even monetization
and inflation. There are two reasons. The first is that the ratio of public
debt to GNP, according to DRI forecasts, will be 41% by 1989, 11 and
will then be increasing at roughly 1% per year; this implies levels of
1
The DRI forecast only gives the ratio of gross debt to GNP. The ratio reported in the text is
that of debt held by the public excluding the Federal Reserve, and assumes that the ratio of
that portion of debt to gross debt is the same, 63%, in 1989 as in 1986.
38 Olivier Jean Blanchard
debt for the 1990s far below those at which such drastic measures as
repudiation or monetization have historically been taken. The second
reason is that, given the current dislike of inflation, the inflation tax is
too small a source of revenue to be an attractive possibility: given a
ratio of monetary base to GNP of 4%, a sharp increase in inflation is
12
A more formal treatment is given in Blanchard (1985) for the case of one country with or
without access to international capital markets, and by Frenkel and Razin (1986) for the case
of two countries linked by perfect capital markets. The analysis which follows assumes that debt
is partly net wealth, so that Ricardian equivalence does not hold.
Reaganomics 39
4.2.1. The increase in public and foreign debts. H o w large a r e these long run
effects likely to be? The place to start is to ask what will be the ratios
of internal and external debt to GNP as a result of the deficit strategy?
This is another impossible question to answer as, in addition to specify-
ing what fiscal policy would have been, it requires assumptions as to
4.2.2. The effects of higher debts. The next step is to assess the effects of
the increase in US public debt on capital accumulation. This question
is even more difficult to answer than the previous one, as the answer
depends on the effect of public debt on savings, and the long-run
40 Olivier Jean Blanchard
elasticity of savings with respect to interest rates, about which we know
very little. Because of high capital mobility, I consider the effects on
world accumulation (where 'world' refers to the set of countries with
high capital mobility), without distinguishing between the US and the
rest of the world. Theory suggests that the long-run decrease in the
I I
13
In the analyses of Blanchard or Frenkel and Razin, given wage income and the interest rate,
the effect of debt on steady-state capital is equal to minus one if the interest rate is equal to
the subjective discount rate and debt is not neutral. The effect is smaller when the effect of
capital on the interest rate, and the effect of the interest rate on savings are taken into account.
14
It is interesting to note that such a change in the capital stock would, under plausible assumptions,
have little effect on marginal products and thus on steady-state world interest rates (this point
was already made by Blanchard and Summers, 1984). For example, if the technology was
Cobb-Douglas, with share of capital equal to 0.25, a 6% decrease of the capital stock would
increase its marginal product by 4.5% and the real interest rate by 60 basis points if the marginal
product was initially equal to 15%.
Reaganomics 41
annual rate of 2.5%, the US will grow out of its higher debt level at no
cost.
The experience of Latin American countries in the 1970s and 1980s
which, based on the similar computations, borrowed heavily only to see
the real interest rate later exceed their growth rates, warns us that the
16
This measure is reported in the Census Population Report, series P60. The nominal amount
defining the poverty level has increased with the CPI since 1980.
Reaganomics 43
for the poor, reaches a similar conclusion. These numbers suggest that,
overall, the Reagan policies have increased income inequality, although
not by very much. I now turn to their incentive effects.
The 1981 and 1986 tax changes changed the incentives to save and to
supply labor. By decreasing tax rates across the board in 1981, and by
reducing top marginal tax rates in 1986, they increased the after-tax
return to both savings and labor supply. The 1981 tax changes further
increased the return to retirement savings; these initial tax breaks have
been partly but not fully offset by the 1986 tax reform.
Starting with savings, the evidence is that retirement plans for which
contributions were partly tax deductible have been very successful. The
amount contributed to these plans in 1985 was equal to half of personal
saving (Hausman and Poterba, 1987. This includes contributions to IRAs
and '40IK' plans, which are profit-sharing plans operated by
employers). But those contributions could well have come initially from
portfolio reallocations, and even from inframarginal savings contribu-
tions later. A study by Venti and Wise (1986) concludes that 20% of
the IRA contributions have come from portfolio reallocation, 30% from
amounts which would have been saved anyway, and 50% from reduced
consumption. One would expect the first effect to disappear after a few
years, so that these numbers are suggestive of some effect on savings.
The aggregate evidence on savings is however much less impressive.
Table 11 gives for 1980 to 1985 the net national and private savings
rates, with and without inflation adjustment. Because the adjustment
for depreciation has been criticized, the table also presents the gross
private savings rate. Finally, it gives the sum of private inflation-adjusted
net savings and purchases of durables, which are in part savings. The
results reported in Table 11 assume that corporate and property taxes
are borne by capital, payroll taxes by labor, consumption taxes by
consumers and personal taxes by those who pay them. Many other
factors, probably more important quantitatively than tax changes, have
affected savings during that period; we would expect most of these
factors to have increased the private savings rate. Unless taxpayers
either refused to consider the possibility that taxes would eventually be
increased, or assumed that deficits would be reduced entirely by lower
spending, private saving should have increased somewhat in response
to public dissaving. Higher real interest rates during the period should
also have led to higher saving. The evidence from the table however is
simply that the savings rate, no matter how defined, has not increased
in the eighties.
44 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 11. Savings rates (% of GNP)
Net national savings 6.5 5.2 5.7 2.0 2.0 4.2 2.9
17
Multifactor productivity growth is that part of productivity growth which is not due to increases
in either labor or capital. Equivalently, it is equal to labor productivity growth, adjusted for
changes in the capital-labor ratio. The number reported in the table is computed by the Bureau
of Labor Statistics as the difference between output growth rate and the average growth rate
of capital and labor weighted by their respective shares in value added.
46 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Table 12. Productivity growth (%)
over the period 1980-85. This poor performance comes largely from
poor productivity growth in the service sector, which has experienced
little labor productivity improvement since 1980. Even in manufactur-
ing, which has experienced 3.6% labor productivity growth since 1980,
numbers for multifactor productivity growth suggest that much of this
growth has been the result of capital deepening, with multifactor pro-
ductivity growth in the 1980s contributing only 1.5%, compared to 2.7%
in the 1970s and 4.0% in the 1960s. DRI forecasts do not predict much
change in the near future: they predict an average labor productivity
growth rate of only 1.3% over the next three years.
This would therefore lead one to be pessimistic about strong supply-
side effects on investment and growth. Yet, investment has been stronger
than would have been predicted on the basis of past investment
behavior, even taking into account the effects of the reduction in
effective tax rates. As shown in Table 6, the stock market has also been
very strong. While real interest rates on bonds first increased, and then
decreased over the last year, dividend-price ratios have consistently
decreased over the last five years. Under the assumption that it rep-
resents fundamentals rather than bubbles, the price of stocks is the
present value of future dividends discounted at a rate including the
risk premium on equities over bonds. This in turn implies the following
Reaganomics 47
relation:
dividend-price ratio = (long real rate) + (risk premium)
— (expected growth rate of dividends)
6. Conclusions
The Reagan conservative policy and its deficit strategy will have shaped
the macroeconomic events of the 1980s. When the dust settles however,
the lasting effects may not match the intensity of the action. Inflation
will be lower. The role of government will have been questioned and
partly redefined. Non-interest government spending will end up lower
by a few percentage points than it would have been in the absence of
the policy. But because of interest payments on the increased debt, this
relative decrease in non-interest spending will not translate into a
decrease in overall spending or taxation.
The deficit strategy will have led to a steady recovery in the 1980s
at the cost of a decrease in world capital accumulation in the long run
and a higher US foreign debt. But despite lower inflation, less govern-
ment intervention and less distortionary taxation, there are few signs
that the 1990s will be a decade of supply-side renaissance.
Thus, lacking the supply-side explosion which would have comman-
ded wide support, whether one judges the outcome as a lot of action
and commotion for a meagre result, or instead as a successful attempt
I I
18
In particular, the Modigliani-Cohn (1979) explanation - which was offered before the increase
in the stock market - that the market mistakenly compares nominal rates on bonds to dividend
price ratios, does a surprisingly good job of explaining the movement in the stock market since
1981.
48 Olivier Jean Blanchard
to redefine the role of government while maintaining high employment
and steady growth, must ultimately depend on one's values: The results
certainly look good compared to those of European conservative policies
and this raises two sets of questions. As both are discussed at length at
various points in this volume, I shall limit myself to a few remarks.
Discussion
William Branson
Princeton University
Olivier Blanchard presents a clear and balanced assessment of the
performance of the American economy in the Reagan years, and of
the connection of this performance to the policies of the Reagan
Administration. I agree with most of Blanchard's economic analysis,
but disagree on the political analysis. Blanchard characterizes the
Reagan policy as a 'political bet'. He argues that by cutting taxes the
Reaganomics 49
Administration 'bet' that it could force Congress to cut spending,
thereby shrinking the economic size of the Federal government. The
tax cuts would create a deficit that would force Congress to act on
spending. On this interpretation, one could argue that the Reagan fiscal
policy was a clever attempt to shrink the size of the government,
David Currie
Queen Mary College, London
Having read Olivier Blanchard's lucid review of Reaganomics, it is
only natural to pose the question as to whether the strategy of a
tight-money loose-fiscal policy can or should be adopted by European
countries.
One reason why a Reagan strategy might have different effects in
Europe is because of the possibility that expansionary fiscal policy (for
a given monetary policy) can lead to a depreciation of the exchange
rate. Indeed, the OECD model suggests that, for the UK, it does lead
to a depreciation. This considerably reduces the attractiveness of a
Reagan policy mix, for it no longer improves the inflation-output
tradeoff.
It is also worth noting that even if the Reagan policy mix had the
same effects in Europe as in the US, we cannot, of course, all succeed
in securing exchange rate appreciation. Further, since debt-income
ratios have been on a rising trend in some European countries, it is not
obvious that we should encourage a move towards looser fiscal policy.
In addition, one should not ignore the harm that Reaganomics has
inflicted on the less developed countries (LDCs hereafter) by inducing
a combination of high real interest rates and an appreciating dollar.
Were Europe to also adopt similar policies, it might only exacerbate
the problems of the LDCs. While on the theme of the international
dimensions of Reaganomics, one might also question whether a situation
where the US has become a major borrower on international capital
markets, while Latin American countries are net exporters of capital,
Reaganomics 53
is consistent with either an efficient or an equitable allocation of
capital.
Blanchard argues that, even if the net effect of the US policy mix on
Europe was contractionary, it could have been offset by an appropriate
change in European policies - specifically, Europe could either have
General discussion
Georges de Menil and Patrick Minford felt that Olivier Blanchard had
underestimated the adverse effects that the current account deficits
induced by Reaganomics might have. It was, for example, possible that
we would see the US Congress approving protectionist measures, which
could, eventually, lead to a very damaging trade war. In that sense, the
fiscal experiment that had been pursued was a dangerous one, and the
next few years may be considerably more turbulent than the author
appeared to envisage.
Robert Solow sought to question various aspects of the 'political bet'
thesis. In the first place, he felt that when reviewing a historical episode,
there was always a temptation to impose a semblance of order even
though it really wasn't there. It is unlikely that, amidst the chaos, the
54 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Administration was actually operating in the clear and sophisticated
way that the 'political bet' thesis entailed. It isn't even obviously true
that the Administration approved of the tight-money component of the
policy mix - for, in 1981, attacks by members of the Administration on
the Fed were commonplace. Solow agreed, though, that the Reagan
c = (r + d ) ( l - T ^ ) / ( l - T ) (A3)
References
Abel, A., G. Mankiw, L. Summers and R. Zeckhauser (1986). 'Assessing dynamic efficiency: theory
and evidence', NBER Working Paper No 2097.
Abowd, J. (1986), 'Real contract wages, employment and import penetration', Princeton University,
mimeo.
56 Olivier Jean Blanchard
Auerbach, A. (1983). 'Corporate taxation in the United States', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
(1987). 'The tax reform act of 1986 and the cost of capital', Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Baldwin, R. and P. Krugman (1986) 'Hysteresis in trade', MIT, mimeo.
Barro, R. (1987). 'Budget deficits, only a minor crisis', Wall Street Journal.
Blanchard, O. (1984). 'The Lucas critique and the Volcker deflation', American Economic Review,
Papers and Proceedings.