Ha-Joon Chang - The Political Economy of Industrial Policy-Palgrave Macmillan (1993)
Ha-Joon Chang - The Political Economy of Industrial Policy-Palgrave Macmillan (1993)
Ha-Joon Chang - The Political Economy of Industrial Policy-Palgrave Macmillan (1993)
Industrial Policy
Ha-Joon Chang
TI-IE POLJTICAL ECONOMY OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY
This page intentionally left blank
The Political Economy
of Industrial Policy
Ha-Joon Chang
Faculty of Economics and Politics
Uni\'ersit)' (~fCambridge
Published in Great Britain by
MACMILLAN PRESS LTD
Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS
and London
Companies and representatives
throughout the world
vii
viii Contents
Introduction 91
Conren~ ix
Bibliography 157
Index 173
This page intentionally left blank
Preface to the 1996 Reprint
While one writes a book because one thinks that one has something to
say that will interest more than just a handful of people, for an
unknown fIrst-time author, it was still a wonderful surprise to find out
that The Political Economy of Industrial Policy has been. doing suf-
ficiently well to justify a paperback edition. Since the book was
published, I have received a surprising number of responses from many
people through various channels. There were some predictable
reactions, be they positive or negative, but there were also some which
I did not expect when I wrote the book. And for some of these reactions
I felt the need to respond in order to clear up the misunderstandings.
Moreover, as some of the issues I discussed in the book have seen a
flurry of debate in recent years, I felt that I should add a word or two on
the more recent developments.
First of all, my use of the' concept of transaction costs in analysing
the relative costs of different fonns of coordination invited a lot of
justified and unjustified criticism. One criticism was that transaction
costs are perhaps not as important as the costs of coordination failure
themselves, and therefore that my emphasis on transaction costs was
diverting attention from a more important issue. This was a response
that I anticipated at various places in the book, but perhaps I did not do
enough to prevent such misunderstandings. I was by no means suggest-
ing that the costs from coordination failures· were less important than
the transaction costs involved in correcting them, but simply that
correcting coordination failures is not without cost, as it is assumed in
many economic theories. .
The other criticism that I faced due to my adoption of the term
'transaction costs' was that I was advocating the purely 'self-seeking'
view of individuals, as many who use the concept tend to be, and that
partly as a consequence of this I failed to see other forms of
coordination such as 'networks' which are at least partly based on non-
selfish, cooperative behaviours. This was, again, an unfortunate
misunderstanding. While I certainly did not explore the network as an
alternative coordination mechanism to the market or state intervention,
this was not because I believed that human beings are so selfish they
are incapable of spontaneous cooperation. As I keep emphasising at
various places throughout the book, especially in the first two chapters,
xi
xii Preface to the 1996 Reprint
References
xvi
Acknolvledgements xvii
The quarter century after the Second World War was truly the 'golden
age' of capitalism (see MargJin and Schor (eds), 1990, and Armstrong
et al., 1991). All the major industrial countries in this period experi-
enced unprecedented growth with no serious inflation and near-full
employment, which resulted in a spectacular rise in general living
standards. This achievement was impressive enough to establish
Keynesian economic management, which donlinated the economic
policy-making of the major industrial powers in this period, as the
ultimate way to run a viable capitalist system, or the 'mixed economy' .1
However the collapse of rapid growth and full employment in the
mid-1970s in most of the leading industrial economies was a rude
awakening to the fact that certain fundamental structural changes in
national and world economies occurred during the 'golden age'. The
rapid absorption of the agricultural labour force into industries and
services eliminated surplus labour and created tight labour markets,
often with inflationary consequences. Investments in manufacturing by
multinational corporations emerged as an important form of inter-
national capital flow, and this, together with the lowering of barriers to
other forms of capital Inovements, made national economic manage-
ment much less effective. Japan became one of the world's leading
industrial countries and the East Asian newly industrialising countries
(henceforth NICs), that is, Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, and South
Korea (henceforth Korea), became major actors in some world·markets,
such as textiles, electronics, shipbuilding and steel. Together these
changes meant massive dislocations in the old heartlands of world
industrial production, that is, the 'rust belt' of the USA and the old
industrial centres of Western Europe, resulting in a fundamental
transformation in the map of world industries.
The rise of new-right ideas and the election of the Reagan and
Thatcher governments in the last years of the 1970s and the early
2 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
The book is organised into four parts. The first chapter reviews the
literature on state intervention. Without claiming to be exhaustive or to
be doing justice to all individual theories, four groups of literature are
reviewed, namely market-failure literature, contractarian literature,
political-economy literature and government-failure literature. It is
argued that, even· ignoring the moral and political reasons put forward,
respectively, by the contractarian literature and the political-economy
literature, we cannot fully accept the conventional case for state inter-
vention based on the existence of market failures because the very
process of correcting such failures may incur costs greater than the
efficiency gains from it, as the government-failure literature has
correctly pointed out.
In the second chapter we develop a new institutionalist theory of
state intervention. New institutional economics has largely concen-
trated on the theory of firm and contracts, but, as we wish to demon-
strate in this chapter, it can provide some interesting insights into the
question of state intervention. In this chapter we interpret the costs of
state intervention as transaction costs incurred (1) in policy decision
and implementation, and (2) as a result of the increase in the incentives
for the private sector to spend resources to change the property-rights
6 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
The role of the state in the capitalist economy has been one of the most
controversial issues in economics since the birth of the discipline (Deane,
1989). Almost everyone agrees that the state has a role to play, but there
is little agreement as to when and how it should act. Perhaps the reason
why there is such little agreement is that state intervention is a complex
phenomenon involving many contentious issues such as efficiency,
morality, power, liberty and legitimacy, to name just a few.
In this chapter we organise our discussion into four parts to make this
complex issue more tractable. In the first section we examine analyses of
market failure which are mainly concerned with the possible failure of the
market lnechanism to achieve Pareto efficiency and with the state's role
in overcoming such failure. Then we tum to the politico-philosphical de-
bate on whether the stale as a political entity should or should not inter-
vene to correct the market outcome, be such correction efficient or not in
sOlne sense. Thirdly we consider the political economy - both right-wing
and left-wing - literature, which asks whether it is correct to assume that
the state servessome 'public~ or 'social' purpose rather than individual or
group interests. Lastly \ve examine the government-failure literature,
which asks whether the state has the ability to intervene effectively,
whatever its intention is.
7
8 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
tify state intervention.4 That is, even if there is a public (collective) good,
it is not clear whether the 'collectivity' to provide it should be the state.
l\S Olson (1965) argues, in a small group, optimal public-good provision
may be achieved without state intervention because in a small group it is
likely that there are individual members who gain so much benefit from
the public good concerned that they are better off providing the good uni-
laterally (pp. 43-52). And even in a large group where this condition
does not obtain, state intervention is not always necessary. Public goods
may be optimally provided even in a large number setting, if some
'selective incentives' (Olson, 1965) in the form of private goods provided
by 'political entrepreneurs' (Popkin, 1979) can overcome the free-rider
problem by bringing individual costlbenefit structures in line with the
social (or group) costlbenefit structure. Of course these arguments do not
allow us to conclude that the public-good problem can always be solved
by private initiatives. In many cases, the use of coercion by the state (for
example taxation) may be the only possible way to resolve the problem. 5
1.1.3 Externalities
transactions will be (or should be) adopted and under what conditions
non-market institutions, including state intervention, will be (or should
be) adopted, as new institutional economics has recently tried.
Some other anti-interventionists argue that correcting one set of
externalities leads to another. Friedman (1962), for example, has grave
reservations about state intervention based on the externalities argu-
ment - the 'neighbourhood-effects' argument as he calls it - pointing
out that: (a) it will in part introduce an additional set of neighbourhood
effects by failing to charge or to compensate individuals properly; and
(b) it creates externalities in the form of 'threatening freedom' (p. 32).
This is unconvincing since: (a) whether the gains from eliminating exist-
iog externalities are smaller than the losses from the newly-created
externalities cannot be determined a priori; and (b) unsolved external-
ities also mean the limiting of someone's freedom -- the affecting in the
case of positive externalities, the affected in the case of negative ex-
ternalities - because one party has the desire to trade but cannot
(recall that externalities are untraded interdependences).10
The moralistic argument for state intervention usually takes two forms.
Firstly, it is argued that the state may intervene in the provision of 'merit
goods', which are 'goods the provision of which society (as distinct
from the preferences of the individual consumer) wishes to encourage
or, in the case of demerit goods, to deter' (Musgrave and Musgrave,
1984, po 78). Secondly, state intervention may also be justified if society
believes that market-type transactions are not morally acceptable in
some areas, for example blood donations or police services. In this case,
the argument goes, the state, as the social guardian, should remove such
activities from the domain of the market and conduct them itself.
Theories ofState Intervention 13
The above argument is often branded as paternalism by.those who
believe in methodological individualism and its politico-philosophic
counterpart, contractarianism (for an exposition of contractarianism,
see Nozick, 1974). From the methodologically individualistic point of
view, the above argument is flawed in that it attaches an independent
will to society, which is no more than a collection of individuals. From
this politico-philosophic point of view, the belief that the state should
decide on what individuals should produce and consume and in what
ways is a first step on 'the road to serfdom' (Hayek, 1972).
Those who believe in individualism-eontractarianism argue that 'the
individual and not the group should be the basic repository of rights and
obligations' (Schotter, 1985, p. 18). Thus it is believed that 'individuals
should be allowed, within defined limits~ to follow their own values and
preferences rather than somebody else's. ... It is this recognition of the
individual as the ultimate judge of his ends, the belief that as far as
possible his o~n views ought to govern his action, that forms the essence
of the individualist position' (Hayek, 1972, p. 59). Of course, this
position 'does not assume, as is often asserted, !pat man is egoistic or
selfish or ought to be' (Hayek, 1972, p. 59). However, no other person or
authority can impose hislher or its own ethical judgement on the
individual, since the individual knows best what his situation is and what
his best option in that situation is. Any interference with the making of
individual decisions is seen as violating the innate right to freedom of the
individual (Hayek, 1972, 1988; Mises, 1929, 1979; Friedman, 1962).
If we do not, or rather should not, introduce any exogenous ethical
code other than that of the individual being the judge of his/her own
destiny, contractarianism, whether of the Hobbesian or the Rawlsian
variety, becomes the only consistent view of the state, or more gen-
erally, of politics. As Buchanan says, 'if politics is to be interpreted in
any justificatory or legitimatising sense without the introduction of
supra-individual value norms [emphasis added], it must be modelled as
a process within which individuals, with separate and potentially differ-
ing interests and values, interact for the purpose of securing individu-
ally valued benefits of cooperative effort. If this presupposition about
the nature of politics is accepted, the ultimate model of politics is Con-
tractarian [emphasis original]' (Buchanan, 1986, p. 240). The ideal
state is then the product of voluntary contracts between free individuals
who found some potential gains in restricting the unfettered exercise of
the individual free win of other individuals and of their own. Contract-
arianism in its most consistent form should be based on the unanimity
14 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
more importantly, who has the right to decide who is responsible and
who is not, if there should be no supraindividual value? Secondly, there
is 'no intrinsic reason why individuals should always pursue their own
good or why they will always do so better than others can do it for
them' (Freeden, 1991, p. 89). As Goodin (1986) notes, people make
decisions on incomplete information, ignorance of their future prefer-
ences, ignorance of the full consequences of their own actions, decepti ve
decision frameworks, the desire to avoid responsib~lity for risks. The
existence of implicit preferences for preferences (for example reckless
drivers and drug addicts are not to be seen as acting in their best inter-
ests) is another case in point. In such situations it is not clear whether
we should regard individual decisions as the manifestation of their
preferences, and therefore argue against all intervention.
In contractarian philosophy it is argued that the state cannot be
regarded as being 'above' individuals, since it is a product of free con-
tracts between independent individuals. Contractarians hypothesise a
'state of nature' where all individuals are free to make contracts but are
involved in a state of war against everybody else, which leads to the
need for the imposition of an extra-individual authority, through volun-
tary contracts, in the form of the state.
This 'state-of-nature' scenario is of course a fiction. During the his-
tory of mankind, the choice has been the one between one form of
authority and another, and not the one between anarchy and authority,
as the contractarians put it (for example Nozick, 1974). Even a cursory
look at the history of the last few centuries reveals that the building of
the modern state was largely initiated by rulers, and not by freely-
contracting individuals (Poggi, 1990). Moreover it is in contradiction to
historical truth to argue that market-type transactions brought about the
state - the opposite view is more correct. The market in its present form
is a newer fonn of social institution compared with other forms, includ-
ing the state. As Polanyi (1957) persuasively puts it, historical
experience shows us that:
[t]he road to the free market was opened and kept open by an
enormous increase in continuous, centrally organised and controlled
interventionism [emphasis added]. To make Adam Smith's 'simple
and natural liberty' compatible with the needs of a human society was
a most complicated affair. Witness the complexity of the provisions in
the innumerable enclosure laws; the amount of bureaucratic control
involved in the administration of the New Poor Laws which for the
Theories ofState Intervention 17
first time since· Queen Elizabeth's reign were effectively supervised
by central authority; or the increase in governmental administration
entailed in the meritorious task of municipal reform .... Admin-
istrators had to be constantly on the watch to ensure the free working
of the system. Thus even those who wished most ardently to free the
state from all unnecessary duties, and whose whole philosophy de-
manded the restriction of state activities, could not but entrust the
self-same state with the new powers, organs, and instruments required
for the establishment of laissez-faire (p. 140).
The view that the state should be regarded as 'a dynamic independent
force' (Findlay, 1990, p. 195) with its own objective function that is
distinct from that of the society as a whole is not new. A stream within
the Marxist tradition, originating from Marx's Eighteenth Brumaire of
Louis Bonaparte (Marx, 1934), has recognised that a certain state may
acquire an 'autonomy' from society, if no class is powerful enough to
impose its will on the state (for example, Alavi, 1972).15 One strand in
the recently popular 'neoclassical political economy' goes a step further
and characterises the state as a 'predator', which, acting as a discrimi-
nating monopolist, develops a property-rights structure and a tax
system which maximise its 'profit' or net revenue (tax minus expend-
iture), if necessary at the expense of social productivity.16 Of course
neoclassical political economy recognises that revenue-maximisation
by the state is an exercise in constrained maximisation, since the threat
of takeover by an alternative ruler from within or without the coun~ry
imposes a competitive constraint (see North, 1981, ch. 3; Findlay,
1988; Eggertsson, 1990, ch. 10).
The view that the state may act as an entity with its own will (and greed)
is a useful antidote to the naive assumption of welfare economics that it
will correct market failures as soon as it finds them. Moreover, when the
traditional interest-group approach has treated the state as a black box in
Theories ofState Intervention 19
which interest groups feed their policy inputs, resulting in some
disappointingly simplistic policy implications, there seems to be some
value in seeing the state as an autonomous entity (Skocpol, 1985; also
see 1.3.2 below). However the approach is not without its problems.
First of all, the approach treats the 'autonomous' or 'predatory' state
as a unified entity. As recognised even by one of the earlier proponents
of the predatory-state approach, the richer institutional context of the
modern polity with a bureaucracy and (frequently) a working legis-
lature makes it difficult to apply this simplistic model to an analysis of
real-life examples (North, 1990a). In fact the most distinctive charac-
teristic of the modern state is the development of institutional bounds
on arbitrium (Poggi, 1990, pp. 74-6). In particular, the 'necessity of
developing agents (a bureaucracy) to monitor, meter, and collect
revenue' (North, 1990a, p. 190) introduces a complication in the form
of a conflict of interests between the ruler, who wants to maximise net
revenue, and the bureaucrats, who want to maximise the budgets of
their own bureaux (see 1.3.3 below for further discussion).
Secondly, talking of state autonomy in the abstract is not very help-
ful for the understanding of real life problems. Whether we call a state
autonomous or not should depend on what issues we are interested in.
First, one may wish to investigate the effect of their different degree of
autonomy on the actions of different states (for example the Taiwanese
state is more autonomous than the Indian state) or the same state at
different points of time (for example, the Japanese state in the late nine-
teenth century was more autonomous than it is now; the Singaporean
state may become less autonomous in the future than it has been under
Li Kwan Yew). Second, different states may have different degrees of
autonomy in different areas. For example the Swedish state may be less
autonomous than the Korean state in influencing investment decisions
of capitalists, but may be more autonomous in taxing them. Whether or
not one should assume autonomy of the state depends on the country
one wants to look at, the time period one wants to study and the areas
of policy one is interested in.
1.3.4 Summary
1.4.2 Rent-Seeking
CONCLUSION
INTRODUCTION
The early debate on the role of the state was conducted in the terms set
by welfare economics. The degree of market failure may have been
questioned, along with the moral legitimacy and the political intention
of state intervention, but no question was asked as to whether well-
informed (with welfare economics) and well-intentioned state interven-
tion can actually improve the efficiency of the economy by correcting
market failures. With the advent of the government-failure school the
terms of debate have considerably changed. Although the possibility of
improvement'in efficiency through state intervention is still accepted
(except by some staunch free-marketeers who deny the existence of
market failures), now it is being asked whether the net outcome of such
intervention is efficiency-improving when state intervention itself
carries certain costs.
We think that the government-failure literature has provided a valu-
able corrective to the naive belief about the state held by some welfare
economists that, ·once we can somehow have a 'benevolent' state, it
will solve all problems. However, as we pointed out in Chapter 1, we
are still left with one important question: Is there any way to correct
government failures, as there are ways to correct market failures? The
first two sections of this chapter look at the infonnation and the rent-
seeking arguments examined earlier and suggest how government
failures may be remedied, if not completely eliminated. The last section
moves a step further and develops what we call a 'new institutionalist
theory of state intervention', which incorporates both the market-failure
and the government-failure perspectives and suggests some roles of the
state that have hitherto been neglected in existing literature.
33
34 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
able to secure the best decision. Whether this is the case depends upon
the nature of the decision.
People's perceptions of the world, which are bound to be incomplete,
tend to become biased according to their personal experiences. In more
practical terms, people tend to develop 'sub-goal identification'
(Simon, 1991). For example Simon (1979) found that '[t]he business-
men's perceptions of the principal problems facing the company ...
were mostly determined by their own business experiences - sales and
accounting executives identified a sales problem, manufacturing execu-
tives, a problem of internal organisation' (p. 501). And when there
exists subgoal identification, it is not· necessarily true that leaving the
decision to those at the locality will enhance global efficiency. When
the problem concerned is of a global nature, the top decision-maker, be
he/she the central executive of a firm or a minister of the government,
may identify the problem (and hence its solution) more correctly, not
because he is a superior being but simply because he does not have the
subgoal-identification problem. If the decision is about the global
efficiency of the economy (which is likely to be the case when a state is
contemplating an intervention), a centralised decision-making structure
may be a blessing rather than a curse.
One more point to be made is that the top-decision makers in the
state decision-making hierarchy should be assigned only strategic tasks
- that is, tasks which relate to the long-term direction of the economy
as a whole - and be allowed to delegate more routinised day-to-day
tasks to the lower-level decision-makers. 3 In the organisational litera-
ture it is .found that, when day-to-day tasks and more analytical tasks
were vested in the same decision-making unit, '[t]he pressure of regular
deadlines and the tasks of supervising clerical personnel usually [gives]
the day-to-day activities priority over equally important, but postpon-
able, analytic tasks' (Simon, 1982, p. 81). Given that any individual's
ability to process information is limited, freeing the top-decision
makers from routinised decisions. will enhance the overall ability of the
state to process information.
2.1.2.2 Reducing informational asymmetry
If designing a decision-making structure that can secure rational de-
cisions at the lowest costs can alleviate the information problem that
results from the limited ability of the state to collect and process infonna-
tion, how can the information problem due to asymmetric information
be reduced? As we discussed earlier, there are two kinds of informational
A New Institutionalist Theory ofState Intervention 37
payoffs to (A, B)
The above discussion shows that when the rent-seeking process is less
competitive, it is more likely that the total costs arising from the
process are lower. This happens basically because there exist entry
barriers into the rent market.. Of course, one may argue that resources
will still be wasted even in the case of non-competitive rent-seeking
because people will spend resources to build up entry barriers to the
rent market. We agree that this is sometimes the case - for example I
may spend resources in building personal ties with the industry minister
in order to build barriers against future rent-seeking contests. However,
in a world with imperfect foresight, the scope for such.action may be
seriously. limited - I cannot be sure how helpful the minister will be in
a later, and unforeseen occasion when I want to bid for a rent. 10
Even if the entry barriers to the rent market are sufficiently high that
there are few rent-seeking costs, there may be costs from 'second-tier'
rent-seeking if the state distributes the rent extorted through franchise
bidding or bribery (see Chapter 1.4.2). For example, if the rent extorted
by the state is distributed to bureaucrats in the fonn of higher salaries,
and if anyone can become a bureaucrat with a certain educational
qualification, people may invest an excessive amount of resources in
education. I I Likewise, if the state extorts some part of the rent in the
form of, say, bribery and distributes it in the form of tax cuts, which are
up for grabs by any interest group, interest groups will spend resources
to secure such rents. These examples of second-tier rent-seeking, how-
ever, still assume that there is unlimited entry at at least one level of the
political economy. However, if entry is contained at some level and if,
as a result, competition does not overflow into other levels, the rent
extorted by the state may .not be totally dissipated. And although this
outcome may have· undesirable political and distributional conse-
quences, it may be a less wasteful outcome. For example, if entry into
44 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
If transaction costs are the costs incurred for the purpose of defining
and redefining the property (and other) rights of economic agents, on
the one hand, and of writing, monitoring and enforcing contracts within
the existing rights structure, on the other hand, the costs of state inter-
vention may also be reinterpreted as transaction costs. InfonnationaI
costs, which are costs necessary for the state to decide on a policy and
effectively implement it, are obviously of this kind (analogous to such
costs for private contracts). Costs of rent-seeking, as costs involved in
the process of redefining the property rights structure, can also be class-
ified as transaction costs (see Chapter 1.4.2; see also Varian, 1989;
Milgrom and Roberts, 1990).20 Reinterpreting the costs of state inter-
vention as transaction costs allows us to make some important observa-
tions in relation to the theory of state intervention.
B
Left Right
Payoffs to (A, B)
B
VHS Beta
A
Beta (0,0) (1,2)
Payoffs to (A, B)
In order to achieve the coordinated outcome, the state need not com-
pletely supersede market transactions, as in our examples above. Indeed
such an exercise may be prohibitively costly, as the examples of central-
planning practice in the socialist countries show (Coase, 1988; for
further references, see Chapter 1.4.1). There exist ways in which the state
can reduce the transaction costs in the economy without necessarily
superseding all market transactions.
First of all, the state can reduce the transaction costs within the
economy by changing the institutional configuration of society. The
state can provide legal backing to organise agents into large groups and
thus reduce the number of necessary bargainings (and consequently the
transaction costs involved). Social corporatism in Scandinavia or
Austria, whereby the workers and capitalists are respectively organised
into encompassing organisations and conduct nationwide bargaining, is
a good example of this - although the transaction-cost aspect of social
corporatism has been little discussed (see the Introduction to this book
for references). 24
Secondly, the state can intervene, through its influence on the educa-
tion system and the mass media, to promote a national 'ideology' or
value system, which will help to reduce the costs involved in the ex-
change of infonnation and bargaining. 25 As Arrow (1974) observed, it
is 'easier to communicate with other individuals with whom one has a
common approach or a common language' (p. 42), and therefore con-
tracts between agents sharing the same ideology will reduce the
bargaining, monitoring and enforcement and other transaction costs
required (North, 1981, ch. 3).26 This is obviously what people have in
mind when they say that a homogeneous society like Japan or Korea is
easier to manage than a· heterogeneous one like the USA or India.
Although this role of the state may be objected to on the ground that it
can be used to foster 'false consciousness' and other undesirable
qualities among the people, it is undeniable that an ideological
campaign can playa tremendously important role, as can be seen in its
A New Institutionalist Theory ofState Intervention 53
CONCLUSION
the state - along with the market, the firm and other economic
institutions - as an important device of coordination. We emphasised
that the state lnay resolve the coordination problem at a lower cost
than the market (and other economic institutions) and thus reduce
transaction costs, which are the costs of coordination, in the
economy. Institution of an effective property-rights system, macro-
economic stabilisation, organising society into large groups, promo-
ting national ideologies, and coordinating complementary investment
decisions are examples of such a role. This type of intervention is
particularly attractive because it is relatively cheap compared with
other types, which may indeed incur large transaction costs (for
example central planning).
Our theory of state intervention provides a framework that can
incorporate insights from the various theories of state intervention we
examined in Chapter 1. OUf theory considers both the benefits and the
costs of state intervention, in contrast with the market-failure approach
and the government-failure approach which deal, respectively, with
only the benefits or the costs of state intervention. 29 Although our
theory is still far from satisfactory, we think it can serve as a good
starting point for the construction of a sophisticated theory of state
intervention that allows us to look at the problem in a more balanced
and realistic way. In the next chapter we apply our theory of state
intervention to the area of industrial policy and demonstrate how it
improves on the existing theories of state intervention.
3 The Political Economy of
Industrial Policy
INTRODUCTION
I{egarding the latter, we discuss the nature of economic change and see
what role industrial policy can play to promote it. We then move on to
discuss possible problems of industrial policy. Problems of
information, rent-seeking, politics and institutions are exanuned.
55
56 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
Despite the fact that· industrial policy, far from being a novelty of East
Asia, has been an integral part of economic policies of many advanced
capitalist countries during the post-war period, it has become an
important issue only recently. In the English-speaking world the OEeD
has been the pioneer in this area (see the series of country studies
published by OBeD in the early 1970s). In the UK industrial policy
became a controversial issue with the (not hugely successful) intro-
duction of industrial policy programmes by the Labour government in
the late 1970s. 1 The famous UK deindustrialisation debate also, to a
degree, discussed industrial policy as a possible way to halt deindus-
trialisation and revive the economy.2 During the 19808, studies of
various European countries' policy responses to the industrial crisis of
the late 19708 also emerged. 3 The issue of industrial policy, however,
has probably been most hotly debated in the USA, especially in the
early 19808, with the Harvard Business Review as the major forum. 4
The recent rise in strategic-trade-policy literature has also been heavily
influenced by (and has influenced) the industrial-policy debates. 5
A major problem with industrial policy issues is that the very concept of
industrial policy is not clearly defined, resulting in heated but often
fruitless debates. A good example of this is the discussion on the postwar
Japanese experience, which inspired many of the industrial-policy
debates. Opponents of industrial policy point out that subsidies and
governmental loans to industries in Japan are small (in relative terms),
even smaller than in many European countries, and on this ground claim,
as the title of one article goes (Trezise, 1983), that 'industrial policy is
not the major reason for Japan's success'. Proponents of industrial policy
argue that the non-quantifiability of the famous Japanese 'administrative-
guidance' system makes people underestimate the success of Japanese
industrial policy (Boltho, 1985). Unless we define what we mean by
industrial policy, we cannot judge who is correct and who is not.
'a situation in which all the facts are supposed to be known' leaves 'no
room whatever for the activity called competition' (p. 182).13 He argues
that '[t]he peculiar nature of the assumptions from which the theory of
competitive equilibrium starts stands out very clearly if we ask which
of the activities that are commonly designated by the verb "to compete"
would still be possible if those conditions were all satisfied... Advert-
ising, undercutting, and improving ("differentiation") the goods or
services produced are all excluded by definition - "perfect" competition
means indeed the absence of all competitive activities' (Hayek, 1949b,
p.96).
If the market fails to solve the coordination problem and if such failure
can produce waste, there is a case for non-market, or ex ante, coordina-
tion (Pagano, 1985, ch. 8). As new institutional economics demon-
strates, the firm (or the hierarchy, in Williamson's words) is the most
representative form of non-market coordination, but other diverse
forms of non-market coordination mechanisms exist. As Winter (1988)
puts it, '[m]arkets appear and disappear; firms expand in scope and then
turn back toward specialisation; quasi-finns and quasi-markets prolif-
erate' (p. 168).18 Central planning is also an institutional device to
solve the coordination problem (Richardson, 1971), and industrial
policy is another such device.
such contracts, and there is a case for state intervention. Orderly exit or
capacity-scrapping arrangements organised or assisted by the state can
take the following forms.
First of all, some firms can exit altogether in return for some side-
payments. Side-payment may take the form of direct compensation by
the remaining finns, as seen in the Japanese textile industry in the early
1980s (Dore, 1986).21 State subsidies may quicken the process, espe-
cially when negotiations over side-payments prove difficult. Mergers
can also make it easier to devise side-payment schemes, as seen in the
reorganisation of the French chemical industry (Hall, 1987, pp. 208-9).
Side-payment can also take the form of an increase in a firm's share in
other markets in return for exit from one market. This option may be
feasible if the firms concerned belong to larger entities simul~neously
operating in multiple markets (for example conglomerates) - the 1980
industrial reorganisation programme in Korea is a good exaraple of this
(see Chapter 4.4.2).
Secondly, all finns can scrap some of their capacities according to
some norm, for example according to each firm's share in total
industrial capacity or according to its market share. The best examples
are seen in the capacity-scrapping arrangelnents in the Japanese
aluminium, shipbuilding, textile, petrochemical and steel industries in
the 1970s and the 1980s (Dore, 1986, p. 142; Okimoto, 1989, p. 110).22
The advantage of capacity scrapping over an exit arrangement is that it
can improve the vintage structure of capital, thus raising overall
productivity (on the vintage effect, see Salter, 1960). A capacity-
scrapping arrangement may need state intervention more than an exit
arrangement does because it is more difficult to monitor the compliance
of the parties involved. It is fairly obvious whether a firm is in
operation or not, but it is difficult to observe whether a firm really has
scrapped its capacity. The presence of government inspectors in
capacity-scrapping processes, as in some Japanese capacity-
scrapping arrangements, may help to solve this problem (see Dore,
1986).
Thirdly, there is the interesting practice of 'mothballing', defined as
stripping equipment down and concreting in the mountings so that it
requires a good deal of time and effort to rehabilitate it, as practiced in
Japan (Dore, 1986, p. 142). This mitigates the problem of credibility
that is inherent in recession cartels by making cheating costly. However
it keeps open the option of returning to the fonner levels of production
if necessary (although at a cost) and therefore avoids the risk of scrap-
70 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
In the first part of this section we discussed why the market mechanism
may fail to solve the coordination problem, and why coordination fail-
ures can be costly. In the second part we discussed how state int.er-
vention can prevent and/or redress coordination failures. Investment
coordination, recession cartels and negotiated exit/capacity scrapping
were examined.
Common to all these forms of industrial.policy is the problem of
strategic uncertainty. Of course the existence of strategic uncertainty does
not necessarily mean that state intervention is the optimal solution. After
all many non-market institutions enable long-range planning by reducing
strategic uncertainty (Schumpeter, 1987, pp. 102-3; Eatwell, t 982,
p. 210).24 Long-term supply contracts, technological cooperation and
vertical integration between firms all fall into this category (Richardson,
1972). In a situation of strategic uncertainty, making one's commitment
credible is vital in working out a coordinated outcome. And, as we
argued, state intervention can help overcome the problem of credibility in
such situations. Investment coordination by the state is a way of avoiding
overinvestment and underinvestment due to the difficulty of making
The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy 71
may cut sharply the transaction costs involved in such contracts. Such
intervention need not involve financial resources such as subsidies. As
we discussed earlier, governmental announcements (for example the
French and East Asian 'indicative-planning' exercise) may suffice if
they can provide obvious focal points for coordination between com-
plementary investments (see Chapter 2.3.2).36 Financial incentives
provided by the state, say, for cooperative research in new industries,
although not necessary, m.ay make the state's commitment to its
announcement more credible by serving as a signalling device (Porter,
1990, ch. 12). Thus seen, industrial policy that coordinates comple~
mentary investment decisions may be essential for economic change in
a world of interdependence, rather than be an obstacle to it 37
In the first half of this section we discussed the nature of change in the
capitalist economY8 We argued that the process of change in the capital-
ist economy is best characterised as a quasi-biological evolutionary
process whereby the agents can and do change both their own 'genes'
(behavioural characteristics) and the selection mechanism (or environ-
The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy 79
two major elements in this argument (also see Chapters 1.4.1 and 2.1).
First of all, it is argued that the state does not possess enough infonna-
tion to decide correctly on the future industrial structure of the econo-
my. This is, according to our earlier classification, the problem of
'insufficient information'. Secondly, it is argued that the state is at an
infonnational disadvantage vis-a-vis the firms that are subject to indus-
trial policy. The firms, the argument goes, may use their informational
advantage to extract more than they deserve on social grounds (a moral
hazard problem). This is the problem of 'asymmetric infonnation'.
With the exception of some staunch free-marketeers (for example,
Burton, 1983), those who employ informational arguments (for exam-
ple, Caimcross et al., 1983; Grossman, 1988; OBeD, 1989) support a
generalised industrial policy targeted at certain types ofactivities rather
than at particular industries (for example, investment, R&D), against
selective industrial policy - the type of policy we defined as industrial
policy proper at the beginning of the chapter. If the state has an the
relevant information, the argument goes, particularistic interventions
may work, but since this is unlikely to be the case, the state should
support: productive behaviour in general rather than pick the winners on
the basis of incomplete information (Price, 1980; Lindbeck, 1981).
can be justified. After all, large modern corporations came into being
despite the dangers of the principal-agent problem, because there are
ways of controlling managerial excesses (see Chandler, 1962). And
likewise there are ways and means to reduce informational asymmetry
between the state and firms (see Chapter 2.1.2).
Secondly, the problem of asymmetric information is not unique to
industrial policy as defined by us, but it applies to other policies too.
Moreover, general industrial policy, which its supporters assume to
have no moral-hazard problem due to asymmetric information (for
example Corden, 1980, pp. 182-3; Balassa, 1985, p. 319), may suffer
even more acutely from such a problem. As contracts become more and
more general, the contingencies to be considered become more and
more numerous, resulting in prohibitive transaction costs in drawing up
effective contracts. This means that general industrial policy can be
compromised by unforeseen contingencies. An interesting example is
the US 1981 tax-code provisions, which were originally intended to
boost industrial R&D but ended up subsidising advertising firms
(Lawrence, 1984, p. 140, n. 45). Industrial policy, as defined by us,
being particularistic in its nature, tends to involve contracts that are
more custom-designed and hence allow fewer unforeseen contingencies
and less moral hazard. The use of plan contracts with specified targets
between the state and individual finns in France is the best example of
preventing moral hazard through the use of custom-designed policy
(see Hall, 1987, p. 207).
Thirdly, the asymmetric-information argument assumes that local
information is always better than global information because it is more
finely-meshed. 45 However, as we pointed out earlier, people with
localised information may make a substantively less rational decision
due to the subgoal-identification problem (see Chapter 2.1.2). If the aim
of industrial policy is to improve the efficiency of the economy as a
whole, it may actually be better, under certain circumstances, not to be
affected by the localised information possessed by the firm. Especially
when the decision involves externalities that are not borne out by the
firm, the state can make a better decision solely due to the more global
nature of its information, and not because it is a superior being.
3.4.3. J Legitimacy
Some may argue that industrial policy should not be used because it
undennines the legitimacy of the state. First of all, by opening the door
for special interests, industrial-policy practice can erode the image of
the state as a social guardian and therefore make people question its
intentions. 47 Secondly, industrial policy gives bureaucrats the power to
allocate property rights and hence creates scope for bureaucratic
corruption. In addition to its efficiency consequences (for example an
industrial license may go to an inefficient producer), corruption may
have consequences for the legitimacy of the political system (Krueger,
1990, p. 18). If industrial policy may endanger the legitimacy of the
political system, should we not refrain from it, whatever its efficiency
gains may be?
Against this view, it should firstly be pointed out that some degree of
bureaucratic control is necessary for any society of reasonable sophis-
tication, bec~use 'many decisions have to be taken in response to rapid-
ly changing situations and cannot,· except at the cost of total stasis and
.chaos, be "left" until a highly democratic decision-making process has
been completed. Almost immediately then, in any real situation it
becomes necessary to delegate powers from larger, more democratic
bodies ... to smaller, more "efficient" bodies. However, once such
delegation has occurred, a great deal of the rea] day-to-day decision-
making power is taken out of democratic channels and placed in the-
hands of small minorities \vhich may then be beyond the effective
control of the larger bodies'· (Kitching, 1983, p. 39). That is, there may
be a certain trade-off between democratic control and efficiency in
decision-making. However no a priori criterion can tell us which mix
of democratic control and efficiency - including the one existing in an
industrial-policy regime - is the most desirable.
The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy 87
Secondly, it is not just industrial policy that suffers from the problem
of democratic control. For example, those who criticise industrial
policy usually support an independent central bank, but it is not clear to
us why the democratic credentials of an official in the Japanese MITIor
the British DTI should be viewed with suspicion whereas those of a
Gennan Bundesbank official should be accepted without question. No
policy is free from the personal discretion of the policy-maker. More-
over other policies may be even less subject to democratic control
than industrial policy due to their less transparent nature (Dore, 1987,
pp. 199-201). Industrial policy usually clearly reveals the beneficiaries
of the policy, whereas other policies (for example monetary policy)
often do not clearly reveal who is benefiting from them. Such trans-
parency may make it easier to exercise democratic control over indus-
trial policy than in the case of other policies, if there is a will to do so.
its interventionist and 'modernising' attitude, was famous for its laissez-
faire and 'anti-modern' attitude before the Second World War (Cohen,
1977; Kuisel, 1981). The well-known Swedish labour-capital consensus
emerged in a relatively short period of time out of one of the most
contested industrial relations in Europe of the 1920s (Korpi, 1983).
Moreover learning from other countries with different institutions
does not necessarily mean that a country has to exactly copy their
institutions. It is often possible to create functional equivalents of
foreign institutions. For example the Swedish 'active labour-market
policy' and Japanese lifetime employment are very different institu-
tional arrangements, but they are functionally equivalent in creat.ing a
positive attitude among workers toward technological change by
guaranteeing them jobs. In this regard, the following quotation from
Dore (1986) is well worth consideration:
[Learning from the Japanese experience] need not mean that we [the
British] have to become Japanese, absorb the Confucian ethic, or
raise our sense of national identity to the Japanese .levels. What it
does Dlean is that we should ask ourselves whether there are not
other ways in which some of the things which Japanese institutions
and traditions achieve for the Japanese might be obtained by other
methods, other institutional arrangements, fnore consonant with our
own tradition. If close co-operation and consultation between mana-
gers and workers seems to be a precondition for rapid innovation in
manufacturing firms, and if it is difficult to achieve this, given our
adversarial traditions, what fonns of industrial democracy or work-
place decision-sharing might substitute for the easy acceptance of
bureaucratic hierarchy which facilitates co-operation in Japanese
firms? If we cannot have, and do not want, lifetime employment to
be the nonn, if we want to preserve a more mobile system with the
greater personal freedom which that provides, can we at the same
time devise schemes which would give British employers the same
incentive to invest in training their employees as the lifetirne
employment expectation gives Japanese employers? If the crucial~
aspect of the Japanese system of financing industry seems to be the
way in which it facilit.ates long-term planning and investment, and
reduces preoccupations with next year's bottom line, is there any
way in which our own financial institutions could be Inended to
achieve the same effect, without necessarily modelling our stock
exchange on Japan's? If inflation control in Japan crucially depends
The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy 89
CONCLUSION
The common reaction to the argument for industrial policy has been
one of suspicion and incredulity. The opponents of it regard industrial
policy either as a bureaucratic meddling that is at best irrelevant - for
example, 'Industrial policy is not the major reason for Japan's success'
(Trezise, 1983, title) - or as a peculiar fonn of state intervention that
works only in countries with a particular culture - for example, 'Indus-
trial policy: It can't happen here' (Badaracco and Yoffie, 1983, title).
Such reactions are more than understandable when thinking that
orthodox economic theory hardly recognises any form of coordination
other than the idealised perfect market and ignores the role of
endogenous technical change and learning.
However, as we have tried to show, industrial policy is a policy
practice that can be firmly anchored in economic theory if we incor-
porate recent developments in economic theory that take seriously the
issues of institutional diversity and technical change. As a coordination
mechanism, industrial policy can be most efficient in a context where
interdependence and asset specificity are important. In this context,
coordination through the market would incur high bargaining costs and
coordination through central planning high information costs, while
industrial policy is likely to incur little of both types of cost. When we
take the issue of technical change into account, industrial policy also
emerges as a superior way to promote it. Industrial policy does not kill
off the profit motive - which is the most important, if not the only,
driving force behind technical progress - as central planning would,
and, through the socialisation of risk, it can promote changes that are
additional to what the market can produce on its own.
Industrial policy, needless to say, is no panacea. Like any other
policy, or any other fonn of economic coordination, it has its own costs
and benefits. Its benefits seem to have more than offset its costs in
success stories like those of Japan and Korea, but we have plenty of
other examples that show that its costs may overwhelm its benefits. The
90 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
real question is not whether industrial policy can work or not (because
it does), but how it can be made to work. In this chapter we have tried
to provide some theoretical grounds for identifying the economic,
political and institutional conditions under which industrial policy
would work and have suggested some ways and means to achieve
them. The next chapter, which looks at the Korean experience,
demonstrates how they have been achieved in practice.
4 Industrial Policy in
Action - The Case of
Korea
INTRODUCTION
91
92 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
Since the early 1960s Korea has shown a truly remarkable economic
perfonnance in terms of growth and structural change. Between 1965 and
1986 Korea's annual per capita real GNP growth was 6.7 per cent
compared with that of 2.9 per cent for the developing v/orld as a whole
(World Bank, 1988, Table 1). Table 4.1 compares the growth perform-
ance of Korea since 1950 with that of other leading developing countries
- Taiwan, China, India, Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Mexico - and of
three DEeD countries that were at relatively low levels of development
in the immediate post-war years - Japan, Italy and Austria. Although the
Korean growth performance was respectable before 1964, it was not
particularly outstanding. However from 1964 its growth accelerated and,
especially in the inter-oil-shock period (1973-9), its growth performance
exceeded that of all other countries in our sample, including Taiwan, the
world's best growth performer in the post-war period.
Mexico (8.7 per cent), India (4.5 per cent), Greece (9.7 per cent) and
Spain (10.8 per cent). Thanks to the country's ambitious heavy and
chemical industrialisation (HeI) programme launched in 1973 (see 4.4.1
below for details), the growth of the Korean manufacturing sector
accelerated even further between the two oil shocks (1973-8), a period
when most other major NICs experienced a substantial slowdown in
their manufacturing growth. In the ten-year period following the second
oil shock (1979-88), Korea's manufacturing growth slowed down to
11.7 per cent, due to reasons such as the slowdown in world-demand
expansion after the end of the 'golden age', the growing maturity of the
economy (reduced catching-up effect), and the substantial restructuring
of the economy in the early half of the 19808. However this was still an
Table 4.2 Manufacturing growth in some selected developing countries
(average annual growth rates)
1. For 1963-69
2. For 1965-80
3. For 1980-87
4. For 1966--72
Sources: UN, The Growth of World Industry, 1973; UN, Yearbook of
Industrial Statistics, 1979, 1988; World Bank, World
Development Report, 1988 (for China).
within the manufacturing sector. As we can see in. Table 4.4, the heavy
industries - International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC)
nunlbers 37 and 38 - which grew much more slowly than the manu-
facturing sector as a whole between 1963 and 1972 (13.9 per cent per
annum as opposed to 17.0 per cent per annum), started to grow rapidly
with the launch of the HCI programme and showed an incredible growth
perfonnance of 39.5 per cent per annum between 1973 and 1978 - as
opposed to around 18 per cent per annum for other industries. Even after
the slow down caused by the advent of the 1979-80 recession (for
details, see Chang, 1987), heavy industry continued to grow at a much
faster pace than the chemical and the light industries (17.4 per cent per
annum as opposed to 8.1 per cent per annum and 7.6 per cent per annum
respectively between 1979 and 1988). As a result the share of heavy
industry in total manufacturing output (in current prices) rose from 16.4
per cent in 1963 to 42.0 per cent in 1987 (calculated from UN Yearbook
of Industrial Statistics, 1969, and Industrial Statistics Yearbook, 1988).
Since the launch of the HeI programme, chemical industry has also
shown slightly faster growth rates than that of light industry, increasing
its share in total manufacturing output from 17.1 per cent to 20.1 per
cent during the same period.
The magnitude of Korea's intramanufacturing structural change can
be put into perspective by comparing it with that of Taiwan. Despite the
fact that the Korean economy grew more slowly than that of Taiwan
(see Table 4.1), Korea experienced an intramanufacturing structural
change of a greater magnitude than that of Taiwan. Table 4.5 compares
Korea's intramanufacturing structural change with that of Taiwan
between 1965 and 1984. In this period, the share of heavy and chemical
industry in total manufacturing output rose by 48.7 per cent in Korea
(from 38.2 per cent to 56.8 per cent), whereas that in Taiwan rose' by
only 17.5 per cent (from 49.8 per cent to 58.5 per cent). Even when
Table 4.5 Intramanufacturing structural change in Korea and Taiwan,
1965-84 (percentages)
With the accumulation of studies that reveal the important role of the
state in Korea, the fonnerly common interpretation of the Korean
developmental experience as a free-market and free-trade economy is
rapidly losing its popularity. 1 However it is useful to discuss briefly the
argument because the more recent mainstream interpretations examined
below (4.2.2) can be seen as attempts to rescue the conclusions of the
early 'interpretation.
According to the free-market view, the Korean economy stagnated in
the late 1950s after it had depleted the possibility of 'easy import-
substitution' in non-durable consumer goods. This inward-looking
strategy was trammelled with inefficiencies due to distortions generated
by excessive state intervention in various markets. Such chaotic import
substitution with multiple exchange rates and across-the-
board protection, largely by the use of discretionary quantitative
restrictions rather than universal tariffs, allowed inefficient firms to
survive and discouraged export activities. This in turn added to· the
foreign-exchange shortage and hence to pressure for more import
restrictions.
98 The Political Econ01ny of Industrial Policy
Note: The series between 1953 and 1970 and the series between 1970 and
1986 are not fully compatible due to changes in the accounting method.
Source: BOK, National Accounts, 1987.
Industrial Policy in Action - Korea 101
Evidence shows that state intervention was pervasive in Korea during its
rapid industrialisation period. As Bhagwati (1987) correctly argues, '[t]he
key question then is not whether there is governmental action in the Far
Eastern economies, but rather how have these successful economies
managed their intervention and strategic decision making in ways that
dominate those of the unsuccessful ones' (p. 285). And, naturally, some
neoclassical economists, including Bhagwati himself, have put forward
explanations of the Korean experience that try to reconcile the existence
of an interventionist state with the rapid growth of the economy.
One such argument is the theory of virtual free trade regime, which
suggests that various measures of state intervention in Korea cancelled
out each other to produce a neutral incentive structure (Little, 1982;
La], 1983; World Bank, 1987). Another is the theory of prescriptive
state intervention, which argues that state intervention in Korea does
not hinder growth because it leaves room for private initiatives
(Bhagwati, 1985, 1987, 1988). In effect these theories argue that,
whatever state intervention there may have been in Korea, it did not
affect the workings of the market mechanism because it was either self-
cancelling (virtual free trade) or porous (prescriptive state intervention).
Below, we will examine these arguments in turn, and argue that they
are neither theoretically convincing nor empirically correct.
South
ISIC Industry Brazil Chile Greece Korea Mexico Africa Spain
[::: ] [~::]
Light lndustry* 1.5 2.6 0.3 7.8 2.7
311/2 Food products 2.2 3.8 3 0.5 8.6 2.9
313 Beverages 1.8 1.5 4.0 6.0 6.4
314 Tobacco 3.0 -1.1 0.2 3.4 4.2
321 l'ex.tiles 0.0 2.1 0.0 7.2 -0.1 6 1.2 -0.3
322 Apparel -0.4 1 2.1 -2.5 9.0 _6 0.1 -3.6 1
323 Leather and n.a. -5.4 -3.3 10.7 D.a. ~1.3 0.4
leather products
324 Footwear _1 -3.7 -4.7 6.6 n.a. -0.5 _1
331 Wood products
332 Furniture and
n.a.
n.a.
-1.44
12.1
-5.5
-8.4
-0.4
13.9 [1.1 ] 0.4
-1.0
0.3
o.a.
fixtures
341 Paper and paper 4.2 2.3 5.6 11.5 2.7 5.1 3.29
products
342 Printing and n.a. 8.0 1.1 6.2 n.a. 2.7 _9
publishing
361 Pottery and china 16.2 -4.0 8.9 -2.8
362 Glass and glass 2.2 -0.4 10.5 7.2
products 0.4 0.6 --0.1
369 Non-metal 4.1 1.55 8.5 1.3
products
390 Other industries D.a. -4.8 0.6 9.8 -1.7 6.9 D.a.
Chemical industry* 2.6 0.6 2.2 7.5 3.47 1.3 0.8
351 Industrial 3.62 1.9 1.4 7.9 3.47 0.8 1.1 2
chernical
352 Other chemicals _2 1.0 3.9 11.8 _7 2.2 - 2
353 Petroleum 1.6 0.3 2.0 4.2 _7 n.a. 0.3
refineries
354 Petroleum and n.a. n.a. -0.2 8.1 _7 n.a. n.a.
coal products
355 Rubber products 2.7 1.8 1.6 11.6 _7 1.6
_7 [ 1.7 ]
356 Plastic products n.a. n.a. 2.3 7.5 4.8
o.e.c.
Heavy industry*
371 Iron and steel [
0.6
South
ISIC Industry Brazil Chile Greece Korea Mexico Africa Spain
* Weighted averages: the weights are 1980 (except for South Africa, which is
for July 198o-June 1981) output at producers' prices (including indirect
taxes and excluding subsidies), except for Greece, South Africa and Spain,
which are at factor values (excluding indirect taxes and including subsidies).
1. Major group 324 is included in 322.
2. Major group 352 is included in 351.
3. Excluding slaughtering.
4. Excluding sawmi lis.
5. Magnesite roasting is included in mining.
6. Major group 322 is included in 321.
7. Major groups 352 to 356 are included in 351.
8. Major groups 383 to 385 are included in 381 and 382.
9. Major group 342 is included in 341.
Source: UN, Industrial Statistics Yearbook, 1983, 1984, 1990.
The basic theme of state intervention in Korea has been the making of an
'independent economy' (Iarip Gyongje) (see various Five-Year-Plan
[FYP] documents and EPB, 1982).11 Until recently the balance-of-
payments constraint has been the main concern of Korean policymakers,
and, as Michell (1982) points out, even exports were regarded more as a
means to reduce the unfavourable external balance than as the engine of
growth (p. 196). Policymakers have regarded the ultimate solution to the
problem of dependence on foreign savings for financing of investments
(Table 4.7) to be the construction of an economy with the degree of
technological capability that \vould permit a reasonable living standard
without a chronic balance-of-payments deficit. It was believed that the
cause of the balance-of-payments problem lay in the underdevelopment
of the capital and intennediate goods industries, and therefore that 'a shift
towards heavy and chemical industries is imperative in order to increase
the independence of the Korean economy' (WP, 1970, po 340) - a
principle known in Korea (and Japan) as 'upgrading' the industrial
structure (also see, Second PYP, pp. 9-10; Third FYP, p. 1).
To Korean policymakers, industrial upgrading required giving priority
to investment, which was essential for growth (WP, 1968, p. 48).
Therefore, macroeconomic policy was geared towards the need to
create an expansionary environment - if necessary through inflationary
measures - which was seen as vital for a sustained high level of invest-
ment through its effect on investors' confidence.
Until the late 1980s, of course, there existed a persistent savings gap,
which had to be filled by foreign savings (see Table 4.7). Although the
filling of the savings gap was believed to depend ultimately on the rise in
income level (a Keynesian savings assumption), serious attempts were
also made to repress consumption demand through policy measures,
expressed in unashamedly paternalistic tenns like 'the need to establish a
sound consumption pattern' [emphasis added] (Fourth FYP, p. 27). The
banks, which are mostly owned by the state, were instructed not to make
consumer loans. The heavy reliance on indirect taxes was also justified -
110 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
against the accusation that they are less equitable than income taxes - in
tenns of their discouraging effect on consumption (Third FYP, p. 16).
The control was even stricter when it came to consumption that involved
foreign-exchange expenditure. For example, foreign holidays were
banned until the late 1980s when the country finally became a net
exporter of capital, and imported luxury goods were either banned or
were subject to high tariffs and inland taxes (see 4.2.1 above). One
outcome of such anti-consumption policies was low passenger-car
ownership, which Y'as discouraged by high taxation and restrictions on
consumer loans until very recently. Despite Korea being a major exporter
of passenger cars, Koreans have owned far fewer passenger cars than
people in other developing countries with a comparable income level. In
1985 there were 73.5 people per passenger car in Korea, whereas the
corresponding figures in 1983 were 27.0 in Taiwan, 21.8 in Chile, 16.3 in
Malaysia and 15.2 in Brazil (NRl, 1988, p. 190, table 9-8). Given such a
clear (stated and revealed) anti-consumption bias, Korean macroecono-
mic policy may be more appropriately understood as 'investment
management' rather than as 'aggregate-demand management' .
life and death for firms (Ito, 1984; Chang, 1987). That is, even when the
increase in the overall money supply was contained, the priority sectors
were guaranteed financing at the cost of non-priority sectors. The unfair
nature of such policy has been widely criticised inside and outside
Korea, but the dominant attitude in policy-making circles has been that
being unfair in the short run is justified in the long run by the greater
benefits generated by the priority sectors in the form of faster growth.
Throughout the last three decades the Korean state has chosen several
industries at a time as priority sectors and has provided massive support
to them. Most of Korea's major industries have been designated as
priority sectors at some stage and were developed through a com-
bination of massive support from and heavy control by the state. The
designated industries had priority in acquiring rationed (and often
subsidised) credits and foreign exchange, state investment funds,
preferential tax treatments (for example tax holidays, accelerated de-
preciation allowances) and other supportive measures, including import
protection and entry restrictions. 17 In return for this support, they
became subject to state controls on technology (for example production
methods, products), entry, capacity expansion and prices.
Non-
Major Content Mach- Ship- E'lectr- Petro- Iron & ferrous
(year of inery building onics chemical steel metals Textiles
enactment) (1967) (/967) (1969) (1970) (1970) (1971) (1979)
REGULATIONS
Entry Restriction x x x x x x x
Capacity Regulations
Setting up Facility x x
Standard
Capacity Expansion x x x
Approval
Incentives to use x x
Domestically
Produced Facilities
Production
Regulation
Regulation of x x
Material Imports
Production x x x x x
Standard and
its Inspection
Restrictions on x x
l'echnology Imports
Price Control x x
Reporting and x x x x x x x
Inspection
RATIONALIS-
ArfION
Rationalisation x x x x x
Programmes
R&D SUPPORT
Subsidies to R&D x x x x
Joint R&D Projects x
FINANCIAL
SUPPORT
Special Purpose x x x x x x
Fund
Financial x x x x x x
Assistance
Subsidies
Direct Subsidy x x
Reduced Public x x
Uti Ii ty Rates
116 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
Table 4.10 Major content of prolnotional laws (cont.)
Non-
Major Content Machin- Ship- Electro- Petro- Iron & ferrous
(year of ery building nics chemical Steel metals Textiles
enactment) (1967) (1967) (1969) (1970) (1970) (1971) (1979)
Tax Preferences
Special Deprecia- x x
tion
Tax Reduction! x x x x x x
Exemption
SPECIAL x x x x
INDUSTRIAL
COMPLEX
ADMINISTRAT-
IVE
ASSISTANCE
Facilitating x x
Overseas
Activities
Purchase of x x
Raw Materials
PRODUCERS' x x x x
ASSOCIATION
Sources: Kim (1989), p. 34, table 3.1.; S. H. Lee et ale (1989), pp. 52-9.
The measures employed by the IDL can be divided into three groups.20
First, there are protective measures to ease the adjustment process, which
include import restrictions on competing products, reductions in tariffs
on raw materiais, price controls, and outright subsidies. Secondly, there
are measures related to the attainment of an optimalproduction scale and
the prevention of excessive competition. These include restrictions on
entry and capacity expansion, state-initiated mergers, coordinated
capacity scrapping and/or exit, market-sharing arrangements (that is
subdividing markets into non-overlapping segments). Thirdly, there are
measures aimed at raising productivity. These include the provision of
subsidised credits for such activities as capacity upgrading (or capacity
scrapping for declining industries), import substitution of inputs (for
example machine parts), subsidies for expenditure on R&D and training
programmes, and joint research progranlmes between the private firms
and government-funded research institutes.
Industrial Policy in Action - Korea 117
As we can sec, except for the introduction of limited lifetimes for
rationalisation programmes, absent in the promotional laws, the major
characteristics of Korean industrial policy changed very little with the
introduction of the IDL. The policy measures used are virtually the
same, and the discretion of the burealicracy remains as great as before
(because the eligibility criteria are deliberately made vague enough for
any industry to qualify). The custom-designed nature of individual
programmes also remains strong.
Between 1986 and 1989 automobiles, coal-mining, dyeing, ferro-
alloys, fertilisers, heavy construction machinery, heavy electrical equip-
ment, naval diesel engines and textiles underwent rationalisation
programmes (for details, see S. H. Lee et al., 1989, pp. 64-72; Kim,
1989). As mentioned before, the rationalisation programmes were
custom-designed to meet the different needs of different industries. For
industries with a need for technology upgrading and involving large sunk
investments - automobiles, ferro-alloys, heavy construction machinery,
heavy electrical machinery and naval diesel engines - the emphasis was
given to creating more stable environments for major new investments
and R&D activities through measures like state-led market-sharing
arrangements, entry restrictions and subsidies ·on investment and R&D.
For industries with satisfactory technological capabilities but aging
capital stocks - textiles and dyeing - the priority was capacity upgrading,
and therefore subsidies were given to producers for· scrapping old
machines and installing new ones. For the (largely state-owned) fertiliser
industry, where the local technological capability was already substanti-
ally developed, the programme aimed to introduce more competition in
the product market by granting sales licenses to more distributors and by
reducing tariffs on fertiliser imports. Coal-mining, which was identified
as a declining industry,· was under a phasing-out programme, which
involved restrictions on entry and capacity expansion, subsidised
capacity scrapping, price controls and import restrictions.
(Balassa, 1988, p. 5287). That is, industrial policy in Korea has been no
different in kind from that in other countries in that its essence has been
to entice firms into new industries through state-created rents. However,
\vhy does industrial policy work so well in Korea and not in many other
countries? This is because, as we pointed out earlier, there are dangers
associated with industrial promotion through state-created rents, which
Korea was able to avoid. The question then becomes: how was Korea
able to avoid, or at least minimise, these dangers?
A part of the solution to this puzzle lies in the fact that the Korean state
is subject to influence, but mainly to influence from a small, exclusive
group of agents, t.he" chaebols (literally - financial clans). Although the
practice has produced some undesirable distributional consequences,
limiting the opportunity of rent-seeking to the chaebols seems to have
reduced rent-seeking costs in Korea in several ways. Firstly, when a
small number of people have exclusive access to rents, rent-seeking
activities will be less frequent and of smaller magnitude because others
may not join in the rent-seeking contests, knowing that they have little
chance of success in influencing the state (this is what Bhagwati, 1988,
calls the 'brother-in-law theorem'). Secondly, since the chaebols as a
group have exclusive access to the rent markets, they need to spend
few resources to acquire information about the nature of the present
opponent, because they are frequently confronted with the same
adversaries in different rent-seeking contests. Thirdly, the fact that the
chaebols are conglomerates, with stakes in multiple markets, also
reduces rent-seeking costs by the 'bundling of issues'. A bargaining
solution can be more easily devised if there are other related bargains
that allow more room for arranging side-payments (Schelling, 1960,
ppo 32-3). For example, in the 1980 industrial reorganisation, Daewoo,
the third largest chaebol, remained in the passenger-car market as one
of the duopolists, but was forced to exit. from the diesel-engine industry
and was forced to specialise in a cheaper variety of product in the
electronic-switching-system industry; Hyundai, the second largest
chaebol, remained in the passenger-car industry in return for forced
specialisation in the diesel engine and heavy electrical-machinery
industries (more on this later).
matters less who gets the rent in Korea than in other developing
countries. In other words. state-created rents in Korea may generate a
certain amount of once-and-for-all rent-seeking costs, which are likely
to be small anyway (due to the reasons given above), but generate few
long-lasting production inefficiencies.
In our opinion the most serious problem with industrial policy is that,
once implemented, state-created rents may be difficult to withdraw
due to political pressure from the recipients of such rents. The
existence of infant industries that refuse to 'grow up' in many
developing countries is a testimony to such a danger (see Ben et al.,
1984). As emphasised by economists such as Marx, Schumpeter and
Richardson, the beneficial role of rents as a means to lure (positive
rents) and force (negative rents) firms into more productive activities,
hinges on the· fact that no rent accruing to the innovator is permanent.
In a situation where rents are created by the state, these rents may
cease to be transitory if the state is unable to withdraw them when
necessary.24
forced dozens of inefficient finns (the exact number was never made
available to the public) into mergers, sales and liquidation - sometimes
sweetened by debt roll-overs by the Korea Development Bank. The
programme eventually ended with the notorious 8-3 Decree (named after
the date of its announcement, 3 August 1972), involving a total freeze on
all curb market loans which were eating into the profits of many finns
suffering financial distress, with a subsequent reduction in their interest
rates and/or in a debt-equity swap (for details, see S. H. Lee, 1985).
After the investment boom of the late 1970s (see Table 4.7), which
led to temporary excess capacity in some major industries, the Korean
state stepped in again with the Reorganisation of Heavy and Chemical
Industries Programme in 1980. Four existing companies in the pcwer-
generating-equipment industry were merged into Korea Heavy Industries
and Construction Co. (KHIC), which was subsequently nationalised on
the ground that the state support needed to make KHIC profitable was too
great to be given to a single private firm. 26 In the passenger-car industry,
one of the three existing producers (Kia) was forced to exit and specialise
in trucks and buses with a promise that it would be allowed back in again
when the demand condition improved - this actually occurred (a
conditional entry; see Chapter 3.2.2).27 One of the three companies in
the naval diesel engine industry (Daewoo) was forced to exit, and the
other two were forced to split the market into two segments and to
specialise (Hyundai in over-6000 hp and Ssangyong in under-6000 hp
engines). In the heavy-electrical-machinery. industry, where there were
eight companies, three (Hyosung, Ssangyong and Kolon) were merged
into one (HY9sung) and allowed to produce only highly specialised and
expensive products. A subsidiary of Hyundai was asked to produce only
for its sister companies. Four other minor companies were forced to
produce less sophisticated and cheaper products. Each of the four
companies in the electronic-switching-system industry (Samsung, Gold
Star, OPC and Daewoo) was forced to specialise in a different product.
The two conlpanies in the copper-smelting industry were merged by
forcing one to buy the other's equity, which was supported by equity
participation of KDB and a moratorium on bank-loan repayment.
Another round of state-led mergers and liquidations of inefficient
finns occurred between 1984 and 1988 (for details see S. H. Lee et ai.,
t
1989, pp. 60-2; Leipziger, 1988). This time, the shipping, overseas
construction and fertiliser industries, which were identified as declining
industries, fonned the focus of the programme. In 1984 three fertiliser
producers were liquidated and 63 shipping companies were merged into
Industrial Policy in Action - Korea 123
The Korean state has played a central role in the country's economic
development through its cunning use of state-created rents as an
instrument for industrial development. Of course such a result has been
possible only because the Korean state has been a strong state, able to
discipline firms whenever necessary. The power of the Korean state has
frequently been underrated, especially by some neoclassical eco-
124 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
nomists, on the ground that the 'size' of the Korean state (defined in
terms of public-sector expenditure) is relatively small (for example
Balassa, 1988, but see Sachs, 1987, for some evidence to the contrary).
However, what matters for the effectiveness or ineffectiveness of state
intervention is not where the boundary of the state as a legal entity lies,
but how far it can exercise its influence. Public-sector expenditure as it
is usually defined is a very poor measure of this. What, then, was the
basis of the power of the Korean state?
It has often been suggested that the Korean state is strong because the
country's historical development left a social structure with no power-
ful social classes to contest state power (Hamilton, 1983; Lim, 1985;
Cumings, 1987; Evans, 1987; Amsden, 1989, ch. 2). The landed class
was eliminated through land reforms around about the Korean War, and
the incipient (largely socialist) political organisations of the working
class and farmers were also crushed during the war and the subsequent
era of Cold War politics. Moreover it is argued that the country's
history of Confucian tradition produced a society where the state
cOITlmands the moral high ground and draws in the best talent (for
example Luedde-Neurath, 1988).28 The long tradition of centralisation
in Korean history seems to have been another factor serving to
legitimatise the power of the central bureaucracy. 29
We think these historical factors are extremely important, and perhaps
are what differentiates the Korean developmental experience most from
that of, say, India or Latin America. 30 The weakness of the social
classes was certainly important in deciding the balance of power
between the state and society in Korea. The Confucian belief in the
state as a legitimate social institution (if not necessarily in particular
governments and individual political leaders), often lacking in other
developing countries, also seems to· have been an important factor in
making state intervention effective in Korea. Moreover there are
reasons to believe that the relatively high cultural and ideological
honlogeneity of Korean society - although it is not as absolute as is
often argued (there have been rather intense regional conflicts) - has
also helped in the effective implernentation of government policies, as
we have discussed earlier.
However we think that such historical factors are, in themselves, not
enough to bring about a strong state and effective state intervention. If
such conditions have been present since the end of the Korean War,
why was the Korean state so weak and incompetent in the 1950s1 And,
Industrial Policy in Action - Korea 125
resulting in full state control over investment loans. 33 At the same time,
the Park regime imprisoned many prominent businessmen on the
charge of having accumulated wealth through illicit mean's (for
example by using political connections)~ but they were later released in
return for their promise to ~serve the nation through enterprise', which
basically Ineant building new plants in state-designated industries (on
the so-called 'Illicit Wealth Accumulation' episode; see Jones and
Sakong~ 1980, pp. 69-70, 281-2). With these two major political
blows, the business community suddenly became, morally, a crinlinal
on parole and subject to 'serving the nation through enterprise', and,
economically, a paper tiger with little power to make investment
decisions - the ultimate capitalist prerogative.
Another important institutional innovation made by the Park
regime was the centralisation of economic policy-making power in
the hands of a super-ministry, the Economic Planning Board (EPB),
headed by the deputy prime minister (see Whang, 1991, pp. 86-7).
The integration of both planning and budgeting authorities within the
EPB eliminated the conflict of interests between the planning and
industrial ministries (which are usually more interested in long-term
investments) and the finance ministry (which is usually rnore
interested in short-terlTI stability), if at the cost of concentrating
power within the government (which may be objected to on other
grounds). Elimination of such conflict made the implementation of
industrial policy in Korea more effective than in other industrial
policy-states such as Japan and France, where such conflict has been a
problem. 34
Even the much-vaunted cultural and ideological homogeneity of
Korean society was not purely historical bounty that the nation
accidentally stumbled on. The Park regime mobilised the nation with
the ideology of 'Renaissance of the Nation' through the building of
Jarip Gyongje (independent economy).35 Workers were described by
the state-controlled media and state-issued school textbooks as 'indus-
trial soldiers' fighting a patriotic war against poverty (although the
labour rnovement was brutally suppressed) and businessmen were
given medals for achieving export targets as if they were generals who
had won major battles. Farmers were mobilised into semi-compulsory
(unpaid) labour for rural infrastructural development a la l\1ao Tse
Tung, through the· Semaul (new village) movement (Michell, 1982,
pp. 205-8). Although not an such ideological mobilisations were
successful (for example, the Semaul movement was much resented) and
Industrial Policy in Action - Korea 127
The Korean state has continued to dominate economic and moral issues
throughout the country's developmental period. State control over
credit, which has been the most effective means of controlling private
firms, given their high leverage, has continued throughout. 36 Although
some of the state-owned banks (the so-called 'city banks') were partially
privatised in 1982, the independence of these banks is almost nil
because of their lending to high-borrowing finns and their consequent
dependence on the central bank, which is under the full control of the
state. 37 In fact, following their privatisation, the share of policy loans -
loans with subsidised interest rates arid/or priorities in credit rationing -
actually increased, from 56.0 per cent (1962-81) to 67.6 per cent
(1982-5), making it very difficult to argue that state control over the
banking sector has loosened (also see Cole and Park, 1983, p. 173). In
addition to their freedom to make loan decisions, the banks' freedom to
set interest rates has also been severely limited. Despite the legal
deregulation of interest rates on loans and long-term deposits in
December 1988, it. was reported in 1991 that '[i]nterest rates are still
strictly controlled by guidance from the Bank of Korea and the Ministry
of Finance, despite the legal deregulation' (FEER, 30 May, 1991, p. 52).
In addition to its control over bank loans, the Korean state has
maintained tight foreign-exchange controls. The buying and selling of
foreign exchange has been tightly regulated, and up until a few years
ago it was illegal (subject to prison sentence) to possess foreign
exchange except for state-approved business purposes. The state's
control over foreign loans and foreign direct investment has been near-
absolute. Although foreign bon·owing and, to a lesser degree, foreign
direct investment have not been discouraged, the state has had the final
say in deciding whether a certain loan or foreign direct investment is
pennitted, and on what tenns.
Although far less important than its control over financial resources,
the state's control over material resources through public enterprises
should not be ignored. The Korean state has owned various strategic
industries, including oil, coal (partly), gas, fertiliser, steel and electri-
city. The fact that such crucial intermediate inputs as oil, coal, gas,
electricity, steel and fertiliser are supplied by public enterprises is
another important factor contributing to the power of the state in Korea.
128 The Political Economy ofIndustrial Policy
Of course the regular threat by the Korean state that it is going to use its
power to discipline those firms which do not comply with its policies
does not always materialise, partly because large business firms have a
strong influence on policy formation and implementation. Nevertheless
the threat is not an idle one and it is often realised, as exemplified by
the freezing of bank credit (on 8 May 1991) to 14 subsidiaries of eight
conglomerates that had not complied with state pressure to sell non-
business land (EID, 1991, p. 20). A still more dramatic example of how
far the Korean state can go, if it chooses, was the Kukje-group incident
in 1985, when the state deliberately bankrupted the inefficiently-run
Kukje group, the then seventh largest conglomerate in. the country, by
ordering its major lending bank not to honour its cheques, although it is
believed that the decision to let Kukje go under was in part motivated
by its lukewann attitude to meeting the ruling party's financial
demands (for details, see FEER, 21 April 1988, pp. 58-60).
CONCLUSION
Of course such intervention by the Korean state would not have been
as successful as it has been were. it not for the historical, political and
institutional conditions we have examined - for example the cultural
and ideological homogeneity of society, the Confucian tradition, an
elite bureaucracy and the state's control over the financial flows in the
economy. However, as we have demonstrated, these conditions are not
entirely God-sent gifts which other countries cannot aspire to possess.
They have been brought to their present forms through an intense
process of political struggle, ideological campaigning, and institutional
innovation. Only when we recognise this fact will we be able to avoid
both the ahistoricism of some orthodox economists who recommend a
simplified and biased version of the Korean model as a panacea and
the scepticism of some heterodox economists who believe that other
countries can never learn from such a 'special' case as Korea.
This page intentionally left blank
Conclusion: The Market, the
State and Institutions
131
132 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
'fhe conclusion that emerges from our discussion is that neither the
market, nor the state, nor any other economic institution is perfect as a
coordination mechanism. Each institution has its costs and benefits, and
is therefore better than others under certain conditions and worse under
other conditions. This means that different countries facing different
conditions can, and should, have different mixes of the market, the state
and other institutions. And in fact, as we observed in the Introduction,
even economies that are usually IUDlped together as 'capitalist' or
'market' economies have been based on substantially different institu-
tional lnixes. In other words, there are many feasible ways of managing
a capitalist economy.
This point, which may seem obvious to the reader by now, however
does not seem to be widely recognised by policy-makers in many refonn-
ing economies of the ex-socialist world and the developing world. The
reform packages applied in these countries are modeled on Anglo-Saxon
capitalism, and they are often a crude caricature of it at that. The possibil-
ity that this may not be the only, or the most efficient, way of managing a
capitalist economy seems to be largely ignored. This is a disturbing state
of affairs, especially when within the Anglo-Saxon economies them-
selves there is growing disillusionment with their own models of econo-
mic management. Now their policy-makers are thinking seriously about
policy changes which recognise the positive role that the state and other
non-market institutions can play in the economy, as exemplified in the
renewed interest in industrial policy in these countries.
Of course this does not mean that the reforming countries would
necessarily succeed jf they were to follow some other model, say that of
Scandinavia or East Asia. If there are many different ways of combining
different economic institutions, this means that each country has to decide
on the exact mix between the market, the state and other institutions on
136 The Political Economy of Industrial Policy
137
138 Notes and References to pp. 8-9
2. It has become customary to define a public good, following Samuelson
(1954), as a good with 'jointness in supply' or 'non-rivalness in
consumption' (that is, one person's consumption not reducing anothers'
consumption). Non-excludability is regarded as an additional, but not
necessary, feature of a public good (see for example Oakland, 1987, pp.
485-6; Laffont, 1988, pp. 33-5), or at best as one of the two (together
with non-rivalness) defining characteristics (see for example Stiglitz,
1988, pp. 119-22). However, along with Olson (1965), we think that
non-excludability should be the primary defining characteristic of a
public good, because a good with non-rivalness in consumption can be a
private good if there are means to exclude other individuals (that is, the
so-called club goods). This means that the public-good problem is
fundamentally a property-rights problem. Good historical examples in
this regard are English public parks, which used to be private goods (Of,
more exactly, club goods for the upper classes) but later became public
goods (for every citizen). Such a change in the nature of the goods
occurred not because the parks suddenly acquired non-ri valness in
consumption but because the rising political power of the commoners
made it impossible to exclude them from access to the parks (a change
in the property rights structure). I thank Bob Rowthom for suggesting
this example.
3. Here it is interesting to note some parallel between this argument and
some Marxist theories of the state that regard the provision of public
goods as one of the major functions of the state (Mandel, 1975; Hirsch,
1978; Fine and Harris, 1979). For example, Hirsch (1978) argues that
the capitalist state should and does intervene in areas 'where the
"principles of exclusion" cannot be guaranteed' (p. 92). According to
Mandel (1975), the capitalist state should provide the general technical
preconditions of production (for example means of transport and
communication) and the provision of the general social preconditions of
production (for example law and order, a currency system) (p. 476) - in
other words, public goods.
4. Mishan (1982, p. 154) suggests that, when naming the public good, the
term 'public' should be avoided because of the misleading connotation
of the term that any good supplied by the state may be called 'public',
and that it should be substituted by the term 'collective'.
5. Moreover, given that cooperation is more likely to emerge when the
relationship is of a long-term nature (Axelrod, 1984), the state can
promote cooperation for the provision of public goods by encouraging
the formation of long-term relationships among private-sector agents -
for example, the provision of legal backing for industry associations or
forum for labour-capital dialogue.
6. The logic behind this is as follows. Regardless of the competitiveness of
the market, firms will equate their marginal costs with their marginal
revenues in order to maximise their profits. In competitive markets, each
firm faces a horizontal demand curve, and therefore marginal revenue
coincides with average revenue (that is, price). In a non-competitive
market where firms face negatively-sloped demand curves, marginal
Notes and References to pp. 9-17 139
revenue - which should still be equated with marginal cost to maximise
profit - will be less than average revenue (that is, price). Consequently
firms in a non-competitive market will produce less at a higher price
than they would if the market were competitive.
7. Moreover, there are non-efficiency reasons to regulate monopoly. For
example it is argued that monopoly has to be regulated because it leads
to the concentration of economic and political power in private hands,
which are not easily subject to democratic control (Cullis and Jones,
1987, p. 182).
8. Anti-interventionists argue that, even when scale economy dictates a non-
competitive market structure, the state should regulate private firms
rather than set up a public enterprise, because private monopoly is better
than public monopoly. According to this argument, private monopoly is
subject to some form of market discipline (for example takeover,
bankruptcy) .and is therefore more responsive to the changing needs of
the consumers, whereas public monopoly is unlikely to be subject to such
discipline. Although we do not have enough space to discuss the merits
and demerits of public monopoly vis-a-vis private monopoly, it has to be
pointed out there are ways and means to discipline public enterprises (for
a detailed discussion of this issue, see Chang and Singh, 1993.).
9. Nelson and Winter (1982) generate some computer-simulation results
where, under certain plausible assumptions concerning firm behaviour, a
reasonably competitive market transforms itself into an oligopolistic one
through a stochastic process.
10. The concept of freedom employed by Friedman is that of negative
freedom ('freedom from'), but it is not the only acceptable concept of
freedom. There is another widely-accepted concept of positive freedom
('freedom to'). On different notions of freedom, see Berlin, 1969.
11. The 'liberalism' of Peacock and Rowley is what is usually called
'libertarianism'. They argue, quite correctly, that this position should be
differentiated from Paretian arguments (for example market-failure
arguments), because the latter are ends-oriented whereas the former is
process-oriented (also see Rowley, 1983).
12. .Hayek (1972) contends that non-market coordination of the economy
('planning' in his terminology) is doomed to technical failure due to
insurmountable information costs. This important point need not detain
us here since our main concern is thepoJitico-philosophical side of the
argument. For a discussion of the informational problem in central
planning, see Lavoie, 1985. For an exposition of the information
problem in general, see Arrow, 1974. See also Chapters 1.4.1, 2.1.1 and
3.4.1 of this book.
13. Although Brennan and Buchanan (1985) reject the 'state-of-nature-as-a-
fiction' type of criticism as irrelevant, they are correct only when one
makes such criticism and at the same time endorses contractarianism (as
Brennan and Buchanan themselves admit; see p. 22), a position that is
not held in this chapter.
14. For example Bobbio (1987) justifies the state's concern for social
inequality on contractarian grounds (p. 136).
140 Notes and References to pp. 17-24
15. For Marxist theories of the state, see Miliband, 1969, and Jessop,1982.
16. According to neoclassical political economy, what differentiates the
market from the polity is not the different behavioural principle of the
participants (always self-interested) but the different constraints that
they face (the individual bearing or otherwise of the whole effects of
one's decision) (McCormick and Tollison, 1981, p. 5). Stin emergent,
this school has many different names, such as economics of politics
(Buchanan et al., 1978), neoclassical political economy (Colander [ed.],
1984), public-choice school (Mueller, 1979), new political economy
(Findlay, 1990), or positive political economy (Alt and Shepsle reds],
1990).
17. In some models of interest-group theory, interest groups - acting as
maximisers of utility (or wealth) - make demands to claim the largest
possible amount of state largesse, which the politicians who make up
the state distribute with a view to maximising their votes, and not to
maximising social welfare. The result often is the generation of policies
that are 'irrational' from the social point of view, for example 'political
business cycles' .
18. From the viewpoint of extreme methodological individualism this
argument is a non sequitur, because if these norms restrict the formation
of a certain interest group, the individuals who belong to that potential
interest group can organise themselves first to remove such restrictions.
However, in the real world, as Eggertsson (1990) argues, 'various
factors work against special interest groups and limit their effectiveness,
including laws against bribery, rules regulating the behaviour of lobbyists,
and public-spiritedness of civil servants and legislators' (pp. 66-7).
Moreover norms may have arisen due to the utility-maximising
behaviour of individuals but they acquire an autonomous life once they
come into being, because individuals who join the society by birth or
immigration after these norms have been established will internalise
them through the socialisation processes.
19. Moreover, even when assuming that there are no unnecessary activities
initiated by the budget-maximising attempts of the bureaucrats, the state
activities may not be fully cost-efficient. The fact that the state bureau-
cracyis in a monopolistic position may mean that there is x-inefficiency
in their activities (see Peacock, 1979b, pp. 123-4). x-inefficiency, as
defined by Leibenstein (1966), is generated when production units use
inputs in the right proportion, but on an unnecessarily large scale. Thus,
even when strict marginal pricing is conducted within the state
bureaucracy, it may operate with considerable slack due to the lack of
competitive pressures.
20. Marxists emphasise this problem when they discuss the need for the
state in a class society to ensure the legitimacy of the systetn (see
Gramsci, 1988; O'Connor, 1973; Gough, 1979).
21. Even from a purely selfish point of view, there is far more scope for
cooperation in a stable organisation like the bureaucracy than in a
strictly atomised world. Firstly, since an organisation by definition
implies a long-lasting relationship between a given set of people, there is
Notes and References to pp. 24-9 141
much more possibility of evolutionary cooperation, that is, development
of cooperative behaviour through continued reciprocity (see Axelrod,
1984). Secondly, the environment to which a self-seeker has to adapt
himself/herself is not just the material world, but also the human actors
around him/her (Simon, 1991). Then adaptation will inevitably mean
collaboration with those other actors (this is an analogy to Dawkins'
genetic argument; see Dawkins, 1986, pp. 170-1). In an organisation, its
members will be treated more as a part of the environment than those
who people encounter on a more precarious basis in theatomised world.
22. The informational problem also has a politico-philosophical dimension,
especially from the point of view of the individualism-contractarianism.
As Rowley (1983) argues, the belief 'that reason is paramount and that
appropriate rule of social choice can be devised to encompass public
sector decision-making in a manner fully compatible with the Paretian
emphasis upon the primacy of individual preferences' is misguided
because the pervasive uncertainties in human life make it inevitable that
such as approach ends up with the imposition of the social decision-
makers' individual preference 'to fill the void that otherwise would
destroy the smooth calculus of social choice' (pp. 35-6).
23. In this sense, the self-seeking bureaucrats approach (see Chapter 1.3.3)
is also partly an informational argument. However we included it in the
political-economy literature because it emphasises the difference between
the objectives of the public, or the top politicians, and the bureaucrats.
An asymmetric information problem would exist even if the bureaucrats
genuinely want to serve the public interest, because of the limited scope
for knowledge transmission (Hayek, 1949a, 1978).
24. It is interesting to note that this explanation of the dynamic rent-
seeking process in a competitive setting is similar to the Marxian
argument on surplus profit (Marx, 1981) and the Schumpeterian argu-
ment on entrepreneurial profit (Schumpeter, 1961, 1987). More on this
in later chapters of the book.
25. Buchanan argues that, unless no single set of winners can secure benefits
on each and every occasion, a 'constitutional revolution' will become
more feasible with the increase in opportunities for rent-seeking
behaviour, since each group gains more than it loses in net from the
revolution. In the case of a single set of groups constantly securing
benefits, a 'nonconstitutional revolution' - or violent revolution -
becomes a possibility (Buchanan, 1980b, p. 366).
26. Of course this point does not hold jf the bribed had to spend extra time to
change the state's decision in the briber's favour. In this case, the bribery
should be regarded, at least from the analytical point of view, as an
implicit wage to the bribed rather than as pure bribery (a pure transfer).
27. That bribery does not have direct efficiency consequences - that it is a
pure transfer ~ does not mean that it has no efficiency consequences. It
may have negative indirect efficiency consequences when it enables less
efficient producers to get monopoly rights (see below). Moreover wide-
spread bIibing can lead to loss in legitimacy of the political-economic
system of the country (Krueger, 1974). The loss of legitimacy may create
142 Notes and References to pp. 29-38
uncooperative attitudes among the underprivileged and therefore more
monitoring and enforcement costs will have to be incurred. Bribery,
however, may have positive indirect efficiency consequences when it is
used as a 'signal' for one's superior ability as a producer (as heavy
advertising may be used as a signal for superior quality).
28. I thank John Toye for rerninding me of this important point.
29. The proposal for constitutional revolution is reminiscent of the 'rigidities'
argument put forward by the new right, whose favourite recipe for a
restoration of dynamism in advanced capitalist economies is to undo
oligopolistic arrangements, enforce the principles of fair trade, break
union monopolies, break institutional constraints that prevent wages
from 'finding their real level' and make labour mobile and market-
responsive again. See some essays in Balassa and Giersch (eds)~ 1986.
For a critique of such views, see Johnson and LundvaIJ, 1989.
30. Market failure does not necessarily mean that state intervention is the
solution. As new institutional economics argues, the history of capitalisrn
is full of institutional innovations to deal with the failure of the market to
coordinate individual activities. The rise of the factory system, joint-stock
companies, multidivisional finns, and vertical integration and conglom-
eration are but a few such innovations (see for example essays in
Langlois [ed.], 1986).
42. See the 'long purse story' (pp. 337-9) and the case of high fixed~R&D
costs (p. 414) in Tirole (1988) for the implications of an imperfect
capital market for R&D activities.
43. Needless to say, due to the limited human ability to process information,
the greater availability of j nformation does not guarantee a better
decision (see Chapter 2.1.2).
44. Of course it has to be recognised that there exists 'second-mover
disadvantage', because the first-movers would reap more rents from
innovation. lowe this point to Sandeep Kapur. See also Landes, 1990;
and Amsden and Hikino, forthcoming.
45. Int.erestingly some Marxist denunciation of the 'revisionist' strategies of
~co-opted' trade-union leaderships in favour of rank-and-file militancy (for
example Panitch, 1981) is based on the same view of infonnation. As
'romlinson (1982) argues, this position ultimately depends on 'a belief that
the experience of the ordinary employee, hislher experience of the
oppressive and exploitative relations of capitalist wage labour will
guarantee the appropriate socialist direction in the struggle. The experience
gives a privileged access to the appropriate means to change the. capitalist
enterprise whereas the experience of the trade union official may lead him
or her to a different and wrong assessment' [emphasis original] (pp. 44-5).
46. For discussions of the different relationships between the state and
finance in different OBeD countries and their implications for industrial
adjustment, see Zysman, 1983, and Cox (ed.), 1986. On the same issue in
the French context, see Hall, 1987. For the Korean case, see Chapter 4.
47. For a discussion of this problem in the French context, see Hall, 1987,
pp.176-80.
48. And he continues: as a consequence, 'harmony can only be obtained by
coercion or by a series of compromises ... and purely strategic con-
siderations may tend more and more to override any considerations of
maximum welfare and efficiency'. It 'may also produce class struggle' ,
and~ '[i]n conflicts of this kind, a considerable part of the economic
resources of a community may be consumed, either in their conduct or
in their prevention [emphasis added]' (p. 158).
49. It has to be pointed out, however, that parliamentary representation (the
representation of individuals as individuals) is not the only legitimate
form of representation. Representation along class lines (as in
Scandinavian social corporatism) or even issues (as in some American
lobbying organisations) are too pervasive to be dismissed as illegitimate
(see Maier, 1987, on different forms of representation).
152 Notes and References to pp. 87-109
50. Interestingly, American authors such as Badaracco and Yoffie (1983),
Schultze (1983, pp. 9-10), and Lawrence (1984, pp. 112-15) usually
emphasise the absence of an elite bureaucracy and British authors such
as Hare (1985, pp. 112-13) emphasise the hostility between the state
and the capitalists as the major obstacles to an effective industrial policy,
reflecting the institutional characteristics in their respective countries.
157
158 Bibliography
Bardhan, P. (1984) The Political Economy of Developfnent in India (Oxford:
Basil Blackwell).
Baumol, W. (1965) Welfare Economics and the Theory ofthe State, 2nd edition
(London: London School of Economics).
Baumol, W. (1990) 'Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destruc-·
tive' Journal ofPolitical Economy, vol. 98, no. 5.
Baumol, W., S. Blackman and E. Wolff (1989) Productivity and American
Leadership (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Bell, M., B. Ross-Larson and L. Westphal (1984) 'Assessing the Perfonnance
of Infant Industries', Journal of Development Economics, nos 1/2.
Berlin, I. (1969) 'Two Concepts of Liberty', in Four Essays on Liberty (Oxford
University Press).
Best, M. (1990) The New Competition (Cambridge: Polity Press).
Bhagwati, J. (1985) 'Foreign Trad~ Regimes', in J. Bhagwati, Dependence and
Interdependence (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
Bhagwati, J. (1987) 'Outward Orientation: Trade Issues' in V. Corbo, M. Khan
and M. Goldstein (008), Growth-Oriented Structural Adjustment (Washington
DC: IMF and World Bank).
Bhagwati, J. (1988) Protectionism (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Bhagwati, J. (1989) 'U.S. Trade Policy at Crossroads', The World Economy,
vol. 12, no. 4.
Blackaby, F. (00.) (1979) De-Industrialisation (London: Gower).
Bobbio, N. (1987) The Future of Democracy, translated by R. Griffin
(Cambridge: Polity Press).
BOK (Bank of Korea) (1987) National Accounts (Seoul: BOK).
BOK (Bank of Korea) (1988) Economic Statistics Yearbook 1988 (Seoul: BOK).
Boltho, A. (1985) 'Was Japan's Industrial Policy Successful?', Cambridge
Journal ofEconomics, vol. 9. no. 2.
Boss, H. (1990) Theories ofSurplus and Transfer (Boston: Unwin Hyrrlan).
Bowles, S. (1985) 'The Production Process in a Competitive Equilibrium:
Walrasian, Neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian Models', American E'conomic
Review, vol. 75, no.1.
Bowles, S. and H. Gintis (1990) ~Contested Exchange: New Microfoundations
for the Political Economy of Capitalism', Politics and Society, vol. 18, no. 2.
Braverman, H. (1974) Labour and Monopoly Capital (New York: ~10nth]y
Review Books).
Brennan, G. and J. Buchanan (1985) Reason of Rules (Cambridge University
Press).
Bruno, M. and J. Sachs (1985) Economics of Worldwide Stagflation
(Cambridge, Mass: I-Iarvard University Press).
Brus,W. (1972) The Market in a Socialist Economy (London: Routledge &
Kegan Paul).
Brus, W. and K. Laski (1989) From Marx to the Market (Oxford: Clarendon
Press).
Buchanan, J. (1980a) 'Rent Seeking and Profit Seeking', in 1. Buchanan, R.
Tollison and G. Tullock (eds), Towards a Theory ofthe Rent-Seeking Society
(College Station: Texas A&M University Press).
Bibliography 159
Buchanan, J. -(1980b) 'Reform in the Rent-Seeking Society in J. Buchanan, R.
Tollison and G. Tullock (eels), Towards a Theory ofthe Rent-Seeking Society
(College Station: Texas A&M University Press).
Buchanan, J. (1986) 'Contractarianism and Democracy'. in J. Buchanan,
Liberty, Market and State (Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books).
Buchanan, J. et a1. (1978) The Economics of Politics (London: The Institute of
Economic Affairs).
Buchanan, J.~ R. Tollison and G. Tullock (eds) (1980) Toward a Theory of the
Rent-Seeking Society (College Station: Texas A&M University Press).
Burton, J. (1983) Picking Losers ... ? The Political Economy of Industrial
Policy (London: Institute of Economic Affairs).
Caimcross, A., J. Kay and Z. Silberston (1983) 'Problems of Industrial
Recovery', in R. Matthews and J. Sargent (oos), Contemporary Problems of
Economic Policy (London: Methuen).
Cha, D. S. (1983) 6ja Do-ip ui Hyokkwa Boonsok (The Effects of Foreign
Capital Inflow) (Seoul: Korea Institute for Economics and Technology
[KIET]).
Chandler, A. (1962) Strategy and Structure (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Chang, H-1. (1987) 'Crisis of Capital Accumulation in South Korea, 1979-82
- An Analysis of Policy Solutions ~, unpublished M. Phil. dissertation,
Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge.
Chang, H-J. (1990) 'Interpreting the Korean Experience - l-Ieaven or Hell?',
research paper series, no. 42, Faculty of Economics and Politics, University
of Cambridge.
Chang, H-J. and A. Singh (1993) 6Public Enterprise in Developing Countries
and Economic Efficiency', UNCTAD Review, no. 4.
Coase, R. (1937) '~fhe Nature of the Firm' , Economica, Nov.
Coase, R. (1960) 'The Problem of Social Cost', Journal ofLaw and Economics.
Coase, R. (1988) 'The Firm, the Market, and the Law', in The Firm, the
Market, and the Law (University of Chicago Press).
Cohen, S. (1977) Modem Capitalist Planning: The French Model, 2nd edition,
(Berkeley: University of California Press).
Cohen, S. and J. Zysman (1987) Manufacturing Matters (New York: Basic
Books).
Colander, D. (00.) (1984) Neoclassical Political Economy (Cambridge, Mass:
Ballinger Publishing).
Cole, D. and Y·. Park (1983) Financial Development in Korea, 1945-78
(Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press).
Congleton, R. (1980) 'Competitive Process, Competitive Waste, and Institutions' ,
in J. Buchanan, R. Tollison and G. Tullock (oos), Towards a Theory of the
Rent-Seeking Society (College Station: Texas A&M University Press).
Corden, W. (1980) 'Relationships between Macro-economic and Industrial
Policies' , The ~Vorld Economy, vol. 3, no. 2.
Cox, A. (ed.) (1986) State, Finance, andlndustry in- Comparative Perspective
(Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books).
Cullis, J. and P. Jones (1987) Microeconomics and the Public Economy: A
Defence ofLeviathan (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
160 Bibliography
Gough, I. (1979) The Political Economy of the Welfare State (London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Gould, S. (1983) The Panda's Thumb, (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books).
Gramsci, A. (1988) A Gramsci Reader, edited by D. Forgacs (London:
Lawrence & Wishart).
Green, F. (ed.) (1990) Restructuring the British Economy (London: Routledge).
Grossman, G. (1988) 'Strategic Export Promotion: A Critique', in P. Krugman
(ed.), Strategic Trade Policy and the New Intemational Economics
(Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Hadley, E. (1989) 'The Diffusion of Keynesian Ideas in Japan', in P. Hall (ed.),
The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations
(Princeton University Press).
Hall, P. (1987) Governing the Economy (Cambridge: Polity Press).
Hall, P. (ed.) (1989) The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism
across Nations, (Princeton University Press).
Halliday, J. (1975) A Political History of Japanese Capitalism (New York:
Monthly Review Books).
Halliday, J. (1980) 'Capitalism and Socialism in East Asia', New Left Review,
no. 124.
Hamilton, C. (1983) 'Capitalist Industrialisation in East Asia's Four Little
Tigers' , Journal of Contemporary Asia, vol. 13, no. 1.
Hardin, R. (1982) Collective Action (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).
Hare, P. (1.985) Planning the British Economy (London and Basingstoke:
Macmillan).
Hargreaves Heap, S. (1989) Rationality in Economics (Oxford: Basil
Blackwell).
Harris, L. (1987) 'Financial Reform and Economic Growth: A New
Interpretation of South Korea's Experience', in L. Harris (ed.), New
Perspectives on the Fi~.ancial System (London: Croom Helm).
Hayek, F. (1949a) 'Economics and Knowledge',· in F. Hayek, Individualism
and Economic Order (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayek, F. (1949b) 'The Meaning of Competition', in F. Hayek, Individualism
and Economic Order (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayek, F. (1949c) 'The Use of Knowledge in Society', in F. Hayek,
Individualism and Economic Order (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayek, F. (1972) The Road to Serfdom (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayek, F. (1978) 'Competition as a Discovery Procedure', in F. Hayek, New
Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History ofIdeas (London:
Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayek, F. (1988) The Fatal Conceit - The Errors of Socialism (London:
Routledge & Kegan Paul).
Hayward, J. (1986) The State and the Market Economy (Brighton: Wheatsheaf
Books).
Heiner, R. (1983) 'The Origin of Predictable Behaviour', American Economic
Review, vol. 73, no. 4.
Heiner, R. (1988) 'Imperfect Decisions and Routinised Production:
Implications for Evolutionary Modeling and Inertiall'echnical Change' in G.
Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds), Technical
Change and Economic Theory (London: Pinter Publishers),
Bibliography 163
Hindess, B. (1987) Politics and Class Analysis (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
Hirsch, F. (1978) 'The State Apparatus and Social Reproduction: Elements of
A Theory of the Bourgeois State', in J. Holloway and S. Picciotto (cds),
State and Capital (London: Edward Arnold).
Hirschman, A. (1958) The Strategy of&onomic Development (New Haven and
London: Yale University Press).
Hirschman, A. (1970) Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard
University Press).
Hirschman, A~ (1982) Shifting Involvements (Princeton University Press).
Hodgson, G. (1988) Economics and Institutions (Cambridge: Polity Press).
Hughes, A. and A. Singh (1991) 'The World Economic Slowdown and the
Asian and Latin American Economies: A Comparative Analysis of
Economic Structure, Policy, and Perfonnance', in T. Banuri (ed.), Economic
Liberalisation: No Panacea (Oxford: Clarendon Press).
Ito, K. (1984) 'Development Finance and Commercial Banks in Korea', The
Developing Economies, vol. 22, no. 4.
Jacquemin, A. (ed.) (1984) European Industry: Public Policy and Corporate
Strategy (Oxford: Clarendon Press).
Jessop, B. (1982) The Capitalist State (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
Johnson, B. and B. LundvalJ (1989) 'Limits of the Pure Market Economy', in
Samhiillsventenskap, Ekonomi och Historia - Festskrift till Lars Harlitz
(Goteborg: Daidalos).
Johnson, C. (1982) MITl and the Japanese Miracle (Stanford University Press).
Johnson, C. (1984) 'Introduction: The Idea of Industrial Policy' , in C. Johnson
(ed.), The Industrial Policy Debate (San Francisco: Institute for
Contemporary Studies).
Johnson, C. (ed.) (1984) The Industrial Policy Debate (San Francisco: Institute
for Contemporary Studies).
Jones, L. and E. S. Mason (1982) 'Role of Economic Factors in Determining
the Size and Structure of the Public-enterprise· Sector in Less-developed
Countries with Mixed Economies' in L. Jones (ed.), Public Enterprise in
Less-developed Countries (Cambridge University Press).
Jones, L. and 1. Sakong (1980) Government, Business and Entrepreneurship in
Economic Development: The Korean Case (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard
University Press).
Jorde, T. and D. Teece (1990) 'Innovation and Cooperation: Implications for
Competition and Antitrust', Journal of Economic Perspectives, voL 4, no. 3.
Kaldor, N. (1985) Economics witJwut Equilibrium (Cardiff: University College
of Cardiff Press).
Katzenstein, P. (1985) Small States in World Markets (Ith8ca: Cornell
University Press).
KDB (Korea Development Bank) (1981) Palship Nyondae ui Jonryak Sanup
(Strategic Industries of the 1980s) (Seoul: KDB).
Khan, M. A. (1987) 'Perfect Competition', in The Palgrave Dictionary of
Economics, vol. 3 (London: Macmillan).
Khan, M. H. (1989) 'Clientelism, Corruption, and Capitalist Development: An
Analysis of State Intervention with special reference to Bangladesh',
unpublished Ph. D. thesis, Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of
Cambridge.
164 Bibliography
Kim, J. H. (1989) 'Korean Industrial Policies for Declining Industries',
Korea Development Institute (KDI) working paper no. 8910 (Seoul: KDI).
King, D. (1987) The New Right: Politics, Markets and Citizenship (London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Kir1.kowski, II. (ed.) (1984) Monopolistic Competition and International Trade
(Oxford University Press).
IGrzner, I. (1973) Competition and Entrepreneurship (University of Chicago
Press).
Kitching, G. (1983) Rethinking Socialism: A Theory for a Better Practice
(London: Methuen).
Knight, F. (1921) Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit (University of Chicago Press).
Koopmans, T. (1957) "fhe Construction of Economic Knowledge', in Three
Essays on the State ofEconomic Science (New York: McGraw-Hill Books).
Korpi, W. (1983) The Democratic Class Struggle (London: Routledge & Kegan
Paul).
Krueger, A. (1974) 'The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society',
American Economic Review, vol. 64, no. 3.
Krueger, A. (1980) &Trade Policy as an Input. to Development', American
Economic Review, vol. 70, Papers and proceedings.
Krueger, A. (1990) 'Government Failure in Economic Development', Journal
of Economic Perspective,vol. 4, no. 3.
Krugman, P. (1984) 'The U.S. Response to Foreign Industrial Targeting',
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1.
Krugman, P. (ed.) (1988) Strategic Trade Policy and the New International
Economics (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Kuisel, R. (1981) Capitalism and the State in Modern France: Renovation and
Economic Managelnent in the Twentieth Century~ (Cambridge University
Press).
Laffont, J-J. (1988) Fundamentals of Public Economics, translated by J. Bonin
and H. Bonin (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press).
Laffont, J-J. and J. Tirole (1988) 'The Politics of Government Decision-
making: A Theory of Regulatory Capture', working paper, no. 506,
Department of Economics, MIT.
Lal, D. (1983) The Poverty of Development Economics (London: Institute of
Economic Affairs).
Landes, D. (1990) 'Why are we so rich and they so poor?', American Economic
Review, vol. 80, no. 2.
Landesmann, M. (1992) 'Industrial Policies and Social Corporatism', in J.
Pekkarinen, M. Pohjola and B. Rowthom (oos), Social Corporatism (Oxford:
Clarendon Press).
Langlois, R. (1986a) 'The New Institutional Economics: An Introductory Essay' ,
in R. Langlois (00.), Economics as a Process (Cambridge University Press).
Langlois, R. (1986b) 'Rationality, Institutions, and Explanation' ,in R. Langlois
(ed.), Economics as a Process (Cambridge University Press).
Langlois, R. (ed.) (1986) Economics as a Process (Cambridge University
Press).
Lavoie, D. (1985) Rivalry and Central Planning (Cambridge University
Press).
Bibliography 165
Lawrence, R. (1984) Can America Compete? (Washington DC: Brookings
Institution).
Lee, S. H. (1985) 'Gookka, kyegup mit jabon chookjok' (The state, classes and
capital accumulation), in J. J. Choi (ed.), Hangook jabonjui wa gookka
(Korean Capitalism and the State) (Seoul: Hanwool).
Lee, S. H., S. D. Kim and S. H. Hahn (1989) Hangook ui Sanup Jongchek-
Sanup Goojo Jongchek Gwanryon Jaryojip (Korean Industrial Policy -
Policies concerning Industrial Structure) (Seoul: Korea Institute for
Economics and Technology).
Lee, Y. S., J. H. Lee and D. H. K.im (1987) Sanup Goomyoong Jongchek ui
Hyoyool-hwa Bang-ahn (A Proposal for Improving the Efficiency of
Industrial Financial Policy) (Seoul: Korea Institute for Economics and
Technology).
Leibenstein, H. (1966) 'Allocative Efficiency vs X-Efficiency', American
Economic Review, vol. 56, no. 3.
Leipziger, D. (1988) 'Industrial Restructuring in Korea', World Development,
vol. 16, no. 1.
Leijonhufvud, A. (1981) 'The Wicksell Connection: Variations on A
Theme', in Information and Coordination (New York: Oxford University
Press).
Lim, H-C. (1985) Dependent Development in Korea, (Seoul National
University Press).
Lindbeck, A. (1981) 'Industrial Policy as an Issue in the Economic
Environment', The World Economy, vol. 4, no. 4.
Lippincott, B. (eel.) (1938) On the Economic Theory ofSocialism (Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press).
Lipsey, R. and K. Lancaster (1956) 'General Theory of the Second Best',
Review ofEconomic Studies, vol. 24, no. 63.
Little, I. (1982) Economic Development (New York: Basic Books).
Littlechild, S. (1981) 'Misleading Calculations of the Social Costs of Monopoly
Power' , Economic Journal, vol. 91, no. 2.
LO (Landsorganisationen i Sverige) (1963) Economic Expansion and
Structural Change, edited and translated by T. Johnston (London: George
Allen and Unwin).
Luedde-Neurath, R. (1986) Import Controls and Export-Oriented
Development; A Reassessment of the South Korean Case (Boulder and
London: Westview Press).
Luedde-Neurath, R. (1988) 'State Intervention and Exported-Oriented
Development in South Korea', in G. White (00.), Development States in East
Asia (London: Macmillan).
Maddison, A. (1989) The World Economy in the 20th Century (Paris: DECO).
Magaziner, I. and T. Hout (1980) Japanese Industrial Policy (London: Policy
Studies Institute).
Maier, C. (1987) In Search of Stability (Cambridge University Press).
Mandel, E. (1975) Late Capitalism (London: New Left Books).
March, J. and H. Simon (1958) Organisations (New York: John Wiley & Sons).
Marglin, S. (1974) 'What do Bosses do?', Review of Radical Political
Economy, vol. 6\> no. 2.
166 Bibliography
Marglin, S. and J. Schor (eds), (1990) The Golden Age o/Capitalism (Oxford:
Clarendon Press).
Marx, K. (1934) The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte (Moscow:
Progress Publishers).
Marx, K. (1976) Capital, vol. 1 (Hannondsworth: Penguin Books).
Marx, K. (1981) Capital, vol. 3 (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books).
Matthews, R. (1986) 'The Economics of Institutions and the Source of
Growth', Economic Journal, vol. 96, no. 4.
Maynard. Smith, J. (1982) Evolution and the Theory of Games (Cambridge
Uni versity Press).
McCormick, R. and R. Tollison (1981) Politicians, Legislation, and the
Economy (Boston: Martinus Nijhoff Publishing).
McLellan, D. (1986) Ideology (Milton Keynes: Open University Press).
McNulty, P. (1968) 'Economic Theory and the Meaning of Competition',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 82, no. 4.
McPherson, M. (1984) 'Limits of Self-Seeking: The Role of Morality in
Economic Life', in D. Colander (ed.), Neoclassical Political Economy
(Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger Publishing).
Michell, T. (1982) 'South Korea: Vision of the Future for Labour Surplus
Economies?', in M. Bienefeld and f\,t Godfrey (eds), The Struggle for
Development: National Strategies in International Context (New York:
John Wiley & Sons).
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990) 'Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs. and the
Organisation of Economic Activity', in 1. Alt and K. Shepsle (eds), Perspect-
ives on Positive Political Economy (Cambridge University Press).
Miliband, R. (1969) The State in Capitalist Society (London: Quartet Books).
Mises, L. (1929) 'Interventionism' in L. Mises, A Critique of
Interventionism, translated by H. Sennholz (1977) (New Rochelle, NY:
Arlington House).
Mises, L. (1979) Economic Policy (Chicago: Regnery Gateway).
Mishan, E. (1982) Introduction to Political Economy (London: Hut.chinson).
Mohammad, S. and J. Whalley (1984) 'Rent Seeking in India: Its Costs and
Policy Significance', Kyklos, vol. 37, no. 3.
Morris-Suzuki t T. (1989) A History 0/ Japanese Economic Thought (London
and New York: Routledge).
Mueller, D. (1979) Public Choice (Cambridge University Press).
Musgrave, R. and P. Musgrave (1984) Public Finance in Theory and Practice,
4th edition (New York: McGraw Hill).
Nath, S. K. (1973) A Perspective on Welfare Economics (London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan).
NEDO (National Economic Development Office) (1978) Competition Policy
(London: HMSO).
Nelson, R. (1981) 'Assessing Private Enterprise: An Exegesis of Tangled
Doctrine', The Bell Journal ofEconomics, vol. 12, no. 1.
Nelson, R. (1986) 'Incentives for Entrepreneurship and Supporting
Institutions', in B. Balassa and H. Giersch (eds) , Economic Incentives
(London and Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Nelson, R. (1991) 'Diffusion of Development: Post-World War II
Convergence Among Advanced Industrial Nations', American Economic
Review, vol. 81, no. 2.
Bibliography 167
Nelson, R. and L. Soete (1988) 'Policy Conclusions', in G. Dosi, C. Freeman,
R. Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds), Technical Change and
Economic Theory (London: Pinter Publishers).
Nelson, R. and S. Winter (1982) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change
(Cambridge, Mass: Belknap Press).
Niskanen, W. (1973) Bureaucracy: Servant or Master? (London: Institute of
Economic Affairs).
North, D. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History (r~ew York: W.
W. Norton).
North, D. (1990a) 'Institutions, Transaction Costs, and Exchange', in J. Alt and
K. Shepsle (eds), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy (Cambridge
University Press).
North, D. (199Gb) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Perform-
ance (Cambridge University Press).
Norton, R. (1986) 'Industrial Policy and American Renewal', Journal of
Economic Literature, vol. 24, no. t.
Nozick, R. (1974) Anarchy, Utopia and the State (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
NRI (Nomura Research Institute) (1988) Sekai ni Hiyakusuru Kankoku Sangyo
(Korean Industries are Joining the World Class) (Tokyo: NRI) (Korean
language edition: Seoul, Panmun Book Company).
Oakland, W. (1987) 'Theory of Public Goods', in A. Auerbach and M.
Feldstein (eds), Handbook of Public Economics, vol. II, (Amsterdam:
Elsevier).
O'Connor, J. (1973) The Fiscal Crisis of the State (New York: St. Martin's
Press).
O'Driscoll, G. (1986) 'Competition as a Process: a Law and Economics
Perspective in R. Langlois (e~.), Economics as a Process (Cambridge
University Press).
DEeD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development) (1989)
Industrial Policy in OECD Countries; Annual Review 1989 (Paris: DEeD).
Okimoto, D. (1989) Between MITI and the Market: Japanese Industrial Policy
for High Technology (Stanford University Press).
Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard
Uoi versity Press).
Pagano, u. (1985) Work and Welfare in Economic Theory (Oxford: Basil
Blackwell).
Paik, N. K., S. I. Chang and D. H. Lee (1988) Hangook ui Sanup Jongcheck-
Sallup Jojick Jongchek Gwanryon Jaryojip (Industrial Organisation Policies
of Korea) (Seoul: Korea Institute for Economics and Technology).
Panitch, L. (1981) 'Trade Union and the Capitalist State', New Left Review, no.
125.
Parker~ G. and J. Maynard Smith (1990) 'Optimality 11leory in Evolutionary
Biology', Nature, vol. 348, 1 Nov.
Peacock, A. (1979a) 'The Limitations of Public Goods Theory: The Lighthouse
Revisited' , in A. Peacock, The Economic Analysis of Government (Oxford:
Martin Robertson).
Peacock, A. (1979b) 'Appraising Government Expenditure: A Simple
Econolnic Analysis', in A. Peacock, The Economic Analysis of Government
(Oxford: Martin Robertson).
168 Bibliography
Peacock, A. and C. Rowley (1979a) 'Welfare Economics and the Public
Regulation of Natural Monopoly' , in A. Peacock, The Economic Analysis of
Government (Oxford: Martin Robertson).
Peacock, A. and C. Rowley (1979b) 'Pareto Optimality and the Political
Economy of Liberalism', in A. Peacock, The Economic Analysis of
Government (Oxford: Martin Robertson).
Pekkarinen, J., M. Pohjola and B. Rowthorn (eds) (1992) Social Corporatism
(Oxford: Clarendon Press).
Pelikan, P. (1988) 'Can the Innovative System of Capitalism be Outperformed?'
in G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete (eds),
Technical Change and Economic Theory (London: Pinter Publishers).
Peltzman, S. (1976) 'Toward a More General Theory of Regulation' , Journal of
Law and Economics, vol. 19.
Pinder, J. (1982) 'Causes and Kinds of Industrial Policy', in J. Pinder (ed.),
National Industrial Strategies and the World Economy (London: Croom
Helm).
Poggi, G. (1990) The State: Its Nature, Development and Prospect (Cambridge:
Polity Press).
Polanyi, K. (1957) The Great Transformation (Boston: Beacon Press).
Pontusson, J. (1987) 'RadicaHsation and Retreat in Swedish Social
Democracy', New Left Review, no. 165.
Popkin, S. (1979) The Rational Peasant (Los Angeles and Berkeley: University
of California Press).
Porter, M. (1990) Competitive Advantage of the Nations (London and
Basingstoke: Macmillan).
Posner, R. (1975) 'The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation', Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 83, no.4.
Price, v. (1980) 'Alternatives to Delayed Structural Adjustment in "Workshop
Europe"', The World Economy, vol. 3, no. 2.
Putterman, L. (1986) 'The Economic Nature of the Finn: An Overview' , in L.
Putterman (ed.), The Economic Nature of the Firm (Cambridge University
Press).
Putterman, L. (ed.) (1986) The Economic Nature of the Firm (Cambridge
University Press). .
Putterman, L. (1990) Division of Labour and Welfare (Oxford University
Press).
Ranis, G. (1989) 'The Role of Institutions in Transition Growth: rrhe East
Asian Newly Industrialising Countries', World Development, vol. 17, no. 9.
Ranis, G. and J. Fei (1975) 'A Model of Growth and Employment in the Open
Dualistic Economy: The Cases of Korea and Taiwan', in F. Stewart (ed.),
Employment, Income Distribution and Development (London: Frank Cass)
Rasiah, R. (1990) 'Electronics Industry in Penang', minleo., Faculty of
Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge.
Rasmusen, E. (1989) Games and Information (Oxford: Basil Blackwell).
Reich, R. (1982) 'Why the U.S. Needs an Industrial Policy', Harvard Business
Review, Jan./Feb.
Renshaw, J. (1986) Adjustment and Economic Performance in Industrialised
Countries (Geneva: ILO).
Richardson, G. B. (1960) Infonnation and Investment (Oxford University Press).
Bibliography 169
173
174 Index
Capital-intensive industries, see Korea, . Competitive markets, 138-9n6~ the self-
Heavy and chemical industries perpetuation of, 8, 30, 31
Capitalism: different types of, 2-4, Competitive politics, 44,45; see also
142030, 156n2; origins of, 16-7 Rent-seeking
Capitalists, 20 Competitiveness, 149n27
Cartels, see Investment cartels; Recession Conditional entry, 67, 71, 122; see also
cartels Industrial policy; Investment
Catching-up, 81, 84, 147n 1 t; see also coordination
Late development Conflict, during the process of structural
Central planning, 26, 52, 55, 64-5, 72, 89, change, 5, 14, 19, 121, 126
133, 139012, 141nl, 146n24, 149028; Confucianism, see Japan, Confucian
see also Planning; Planning debate tradition in; Korea, Confucian
Centralisation (and decentralisation), tradition in
35-6,53,124 Congleton, R., 38, 39
Cha, D., 156n36 Conglomerates,. 142n30; see also Korea,
Chaebols, see Korea, chaebols chaebols
Chandler, A" 82 Constant returns to scale, see Returns to
Chang, H-J., 96, 111, 139n8, 15206, scale
153nl1,156n35 Constitutional revolution, see Buchanan,
Chemical industries, see Korea, heavy and on constitutional revolution
chemical industries Contractarianism, 5, 7, 12--18, 31,
Chicago school, 18, 20 1390n13-14
Chile, 92, 93, 94, 103-4 Contracts, 5, 11, 12-4, 15,47,68--9, 75,
China, 53, 92, 93, 94 82, 132
Class interests, 20, 146n26 binding, 42-3,82, 149n24
Clientelism, 22, 154025 enforcement of, 11
Coase, R, 11,49,52, 132, 134, 13708, plan contracts, see Plan contracts
144016, 156n2 social contracts, see Contractarianism
Cohen, S., 39,53,56,88, 147n9, writing of, 47-8
153n18 Cooperation, 138n5, 140-1021
Colander, D., 27, 140016 Coordination, 41, 70, 72,83,89, 146n27,
Cole, D., 127 148n14, 149n28
Collective action problem, 8-9, 14-5, ex ante VS. ex post, 49, 53, 54, 62, 63,
20-1.,3] 132, 133, 135
and public goods, 8-9 failure of, 49,50,63, 145022
in rent-seeking, . 38, 40--1 generalised, 51-2
selective incentives to overcome, 21 and information, 73, 74
see also Public goods; Olson pure, 50, 145021
Collusion, 9,42,43, 112; see also Corden, M., 59, 82
Cooperation; Cartels Corporatism
Colonialism, 155031 social corporatism, see Social
Communism, 148n15 corporatism
Comparative advantage, 98, J01 Japanese, see Japan, corporatistn in
Competition, 38, 59, 73, 76, 141n24, Corruption, 85, 86
144013, 145n22, 148n12, Costs and benefits: private vs. social, 7,9,
1480nl6-7 10,29
as a process vs. as a state of affairs, Costs: production vs. transaction, see
62-3, 148n13, 149n28 Production cost~; Transaction costs
in R&D, 77 Cox, A., 147n3, 151n~6
in rent-seeking, 41-2, 43, 44-5, 53, Creative destruction, 82; see also
62-3 Schumpeter
socially wasteful, 64-5, 111-12, 114, Credibility, 70-1
125,128 Credible commitments, 43, 70-1, 134
Index 175
Credit rationing, see Korea, credit policy Dynamic efficiency, 44, 72, 79, 121, 135,
in 141 n24; see also Schumpeter
Cullis,J., 137,139,156 Eatwell, J., 70
Culture, and economic development, see Economic change, 5, 72, 73, 74-5, 78;
Japan, Confucian tradition in; Korea, and interdependence, 75-6, 79
Confucian tradition in Economic costs, 46-8; see also Costs
Cumings, B., 124 Economic development, see Development
Cumulative causation, 74, 150033 Economic growth, 44, 72; see also Korea,
economic growth of
Dahlman, C' 11
f Economic management, 1-3; see also
Dahmen., E, 150n37 Social corporatism; Industrial policy
Datta~Chauduri, M., 155n30 Economic restructuring, 2
David, P., 51,75 Economies of scale, 41, 65, 66, 84, 111,
Dawkins, R., 73, 141n21 112, 145023; see also Returns to
De-industrialisation, 56-60 scale
Deadweight loss, 9,27,66,67,82 Education, 11,29,52, 143nll
Deane, P., 7 Efficiency, 23,30,33,86, 101, 120, 133,
Decentralisation, see Centralisation 139n7, 141n27, 144015, 145n20,
Decision-making, 35-7, 85 151n49
Declining industries, 68-9, 1 t 2, 114, dynamic, see Dynamic efficiency
153n19 static, see Static efficiency
Decreasing returns to scale, see Returns to Eggertsson, T., 18,23, 140n18, 144n16
scale Ellman, M., 26
Demand downturn, see Recession cartels; Elster, J., 8, 11,39
Capacity scrapping Enclosure, 16
Democracy, 88 Enforcement, 15,47,52; see also
Democratic control, 86-7, 134, 13907 Contracts, enforcement of
Demsetz, H., 10,46,47,62, 144n15 Entrepreneurship, 82-4; productive and
Denmark, 3 unproductive, 82-4; see also
Deper.dency, 153nl1 Schumpeter
Development, 82, 123, 155n28, 156035, Entry baniers, 10,20,28-31,38,45, 76;
142n3 to rent-seeking markets, 41-3, 45
Deyo, F., 137n7 Equilibrium, 50, 51; see also General
Dictatorship, 22 equilibrium
Directly unproductive profit-seeking Evans, P., 113, 124, 146n29, 153n15
(DUP), see Rent-seeking Evolution, 72, 150031
Disciplining, of business, 135 biological vs. social, 72-4
Distortion, 10,97, 101; see also as a Darwinian vs. Lamarckian process,
Allocative efficiency; Korea, virtual 73-4
free trade Evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS), 63;
Diversity, 151n41 see also Game theory
of innovatory sources, i 77-8. Excess capacity, 30, 122; see also
of institutional mix, 2-4, 135 Capacity scrapping; Exit
Division of labour, 64, 131 Exchange rates, 97, 98, 108
Dobb, M., 26,83,85, 148n14 Exit, 60,65,67,69-71, 73, 116, 122
Donges, J., 59 Export targets, see Korea, export targeting
Dore, R., 67,68,69, 70, 71, 81, 87-8, in
13707, 147n9, 148-9021, External shocks, 66
1490022-24, 149025, 149n27, Extemali ties, 10-2,49, 74, 77, 145023,
150035, 153n14 153n16
Dornbusch, R., 99, 14706, 152n5 definition of, 10
Dosi, G., 13709 network, see Network externalities
Duchene, F., 14703 pecuniary, see Pecuniary externalities
176 Index
Externalities cont. General industrial policy, see Industrial
positive and negative, 143nl1 policy, general vs. selective
Germany, West, 87,117, 118, 146n26
Gerschenkron, A., 81
Fairness, 40, 69-71
Ghemawat, P., 68
Farrell J., 143n6
Giersch, H., 142029
FeL, 98, 15201
Gintis, H., 147n7
Findlay, R., 18, 140n16
Glyn, A., 13704
Fine, B., 138n3
Golden Age, of capitalism, 1, 93
Fisher, F., 14309
Goldthorpe, J, 137n4
Fishlow, A., 22, 155n30
Goodin, R., 16,21,24
Five-year plans, see Korea, Five-Year
Gough, I., 20,14On20
Plans; Planning; Central planning
Gould, S., 73
Flexibility, 6, 70-1
Government, see State
Focalpoint, 53,71,76,131-2 .
Government failure, 4, 5, 25-31, 33,
Foreign debt, of Korea, see Korea, foreIgn
34-45, 48, 53, 54, 132; see also
borrowing by
Infonnation problem; Market failure;
Foreign direct investments (PDI), in
Rent-seeking
Korea, see Korea, foreign direct
Government intervention, see State
investment in
intervention
France
Government-business relationship, 37,
basic industries in, 153n 18
87, 121
bureaucracy of, 38, 86, 151047
Gramsci, A., 140n20
financial sector in, 151n46
Greece, 94, 103-4
indicative planning in, 39, 53, 76,
Green, F., 13703
153n18, 156n34
Grossman, G., 79,80
industrial policy in, 82-4,91, 113.
Growth, see Economic growth
147n9, 150n32, 15On39
Guided capitalism, see Korea, Gyodo
plan contracts in 37, 82
JabonJui
Franchise bidding, 28, 30, 43
Fransman, M., 137n9
Hadley, E., 35
Free rider problem, 9,21; see also
Hall, P., 37,69,82,84, 137nl, 146027,
Collective action problem 147n9, 150032, 150n39, 151046,
Free trade, 97, 101, 102; see also Korea,
151047, 153nI3,-156n34
trade policy; Virtual free trade
Halliday, J0' 127, 155031
Free trade zone (FrZ), see Korea, free
Hamilton, C., 124
trade zones
Hard state, see State
Freeden, M., 16
Hardin, R., 8, 20
Freedom, 107, 139n 10
Hare, P., 152050
Friedman, M., 10, 12, 13, 15, 139nl0
Hargreaves Heap, S., 34
Fudenberg, D., 68
Harris, L., 99, 138n3
Full employment, 1, 29
Hayek, F., 5, 13, 14, 61, 62, 63, 72, 73,
76, 77, 139012, 141023, 142n2,
Gamble, A., 137n2 148013
Game theory Hayward, J., 37, 14709
mixed strategy in, 63, 143n9 Heavy and chemical industrialisation
evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS) in, (HCI), see Korea, heavy and
63 chemical industries
war of attrition in, 68, 77 Heavy industries, see Korea, heavy and
side payments and, 120, 148-90n21-2 chemical industries
strategic uncertainty in, 42, 66, 70, 83, Heiner, R., 149024
143n9, 145n23 Hierarchy, 25,36,64,88
General equilibrium, 132 Hikino, T., 144014, 151n44 154n22
Index 177
Hindess, B 0' 20 and rent-seeking, 82-4
Hirsch, F., 138n3 and technological change, 66-70,
Hirschman, A., 11, 23, 37, 45, 150n37 74-9
Hobbes, T., 13 transparency of, 86
Hodgson, G., 13, 74 see also France; Japan; Korea; UK;
Hong Kong, 1 USA
Hout, T., 37,67,68, 76, 87, 118, 137n7, Industrial reorganisation, see Korea,
147nn9-10, 150n38, 151n40, 152n7, industrial reorganisation in
153016, 153nn18-9 Industrial restructuring, 1, 3
Hughes, A., 155n30 Industrial targeting, see Targeting
Industrial upgrading, see Upgrading;
Ideology Japan, industrial policy; Korea,
as a device to overcome collective industrial policy
action problem, 21 Industrialisation, 53
as a device to reduce transaction costs, Industry associations, 40, t 16
52,54 Infant industry protection, 26, 30, 45, 76,
as a set of social norms and values vs. 121
as false belief, 52-3, 146n25 Inflation, 22
Import restrictions, see Korea, trade policy Information, 72, 134, 139012, 141 n23
Import substitution industrialisation (lSI), asymmetric, 26,27,36-7, 81-2,
98-9,102,116 141n23, 142n4
chaotic, 97 costs of gathering and processing, 11,
easy, 97 27,35-6,47,53
Incentive neutrality, see Korea, incentive insufficient 26-7, 35-6, 80-1
neutrality in; Virtual free trade localised vs. global, 36
Increasing returns to scale, see Returns to and state intervention, 26-7
scale with externalities, 79-82
Independent economy, see Korea, Jarip Infrastructure, 118, 126
Gyongji Innovation, 27-8,44; see also
India, 52, 92, 93, 94, 142n5, 155n30 Schumpeter; Institutions,
Indicative planning, 39, 53, 76, 153018, institutional innovation
156n34; see also France, indicative Institutional design, 27, 37
planning in; Japan, indicative Institutional innovation, see Institutions,
planning in; Korea, Five-Year Plan institutional innovation
in Institutions, 56, 77, 87, 88, 91, 132, 133,
Individualism, 13, 14, 15, 155n30 139, 152n2
Industrial policy, 3-4, 54, 55-90, 119, institutional innovation, 27, 87,
121, 147n6, 14709, 148n18, 152n50 142n30; see also Korea,
conditional entry, 67, 71, 122 institutional innovation in
and coordination failure, 61-72, 73, Insufficient information, see Information,
75-7 insufficient
debates on, 56-61 Interdependence, 65-6
definitions of, 58-61 and economic changes, 75-6, 79
and elite bureaucracy, 84-6 and externalities, 10-1
and evolution, 71-89 see also Externalities
general vs. selective, 60-1,80,82 Interest-group politics, 18, 19-22, 31, 43,
and information problem, 79-82 86,14On17
logic of, 61-79 Interest groups, see Interest-group politics
optimal entry, 66-7 Intervention, state, see State intervention
and picking the winner, 39, 73, 80, 81 Investment cartels, see Investment
and political economy, 55-90 coordination
problems of, 79-89 Investment coordination, 66-7, 70-83;
and the product cycle, 76-9 see also Industrial policy
178 Index
Investment management, 110 codifiability of, 72, 74-6, 134, 149n29,
Italy, 92, 117, 146n26 149030
lto, K., 111 dispersed, 73, 131
tacit, 46
Jacquemin. A., 137n6, 14703 utilisation of, 73
Japan see also Hayak
administrative guidance, 53 Koopmans, T., 50, 145023
aluminium industry in, 69, 149n27 Korea (South)
automobile industry, 118, 153n21 antitrust policy in, 111-12
Bank of Japan, 118 automobile industry in, 114, 122,
bureaucracy, 38 154027
Confucian tradition in, 88, 155029 balance of payments in, 109
corporatism in, 155n31 Bank of Korea, 127
industrial policy in, 69, 81, 86, 87, 88, bank nationalisation in, 125-6
89,91, 113,14709, 147nnl0-11, bank privatisation in, 127
15207, 153018 basic industries in, 113
indicative planning in, 39,53 Blue House, 121
Japan Export-Import Bank, 153-4021 bureaucracy in, 98, 117, ]24, 129
Japan External Trade Organisation catching up by, 93,97
(JETRO), 145n23 chaebols, 120, 123-4
Meiji Restoration in, 155031 comparative industrial performance of,
Ministry of International Trade and 103-4, 155n30, 156n36
Industry (MITI), 35,53, 81, 87, competition policy in, 112, 117
92,93,118,13707,145023, Confucian tradition in, 124-5,129,
148n20, 153n16, 153n18 155nn28-29
shipbuilding industry in, 69, 15208 credit policy in, 102, 128, 153019,
Structurally Depressed Industries Law, 154n23, 156037
153011 Daewoo group 122, 154n27
vision for the future economy, 53, 81 economic development of, 135
Jessop, B., 140n15 economic growth of, 92
Johnson, B., 13709, 142n29, 151041 Economic Planning Board, 109, 111,
Johnson, C., 35,39,53,56,59,87, 126, 152010, 154n21
137no6-7, 147n9, 156n34 export targeting in, 114, 126
Jones, L., 8,23, 108, 114, 126, 137n7, financial reform in, 99, 107
147n9, 15201 fiscal policy in, 109-10, 15204
Jones, P., 8,23, 13701, 139n7 Five-Year Plan in, 109-10, 113, 114,
Jorde, T., 78 125, 152010, 155032
foreign borrowing by, 127
Kahneman, D., 24 foreign direct investment in, 112, 127
Kaldor, N., 150023 Free Trade Zones io, 113
Kapur, S., 151n44 free-market view of, 97, 15201
Katzenstein, P., 137n4 gov<rrnment-business relationship in,
Kenya, 94 121
Keynes, J. M., 65 Gyodo Jabon Jui (Guided Capitalism),
Khan, M.A., 62 125-6
Khan, M. H., 22, 121, 154025 heavy and chemical industries in, 93,
Kim, J. H., 116,153020 96, 102, 104, 107, 109, Ill, 113,
King, D., 137n2 ]22, 125
Kirzkowski, H., 147n5 Hyundai group, 108, 120, 122
Kirzner, I., 72, 83 'Illicit Wealth' episode in, ]26
Kitching, G., 21,86 import substitution industrialisation in,
Knight, F., 63 97-9,102,116
Knowledge incentive neutrality in, 101-2
Index 179
Industrial Development Law in, 114, technology policy in, 113, 118, 128
117,154024 trade policy in, 97-8, 105-6, 116-17
industrial policy in, 91, 97, 108-113, virtual free trade in, 101-6
128-9, 147n9 Korpi, W., 88
industrial policy, the economics of, Krueger, A., 28,29,85, 101, 119,
113-23 141027, 142n5
industrial policy, the politics of, 123-8 Krugman, P., 147n5,147011
industrial reorganisation in, 111, Kuisel, R. 88
122-3
institutional innovation in, 126-7, 129 Labour market, I, 2, 60, 87-8
investments in, 100 Labour process, 46, 131, 144nI5, 147n7,
Jarip Gyongje (Independent Economy), 151n45
109, 126 Labour-intensive industries, 59,98
Kia group, 122 Laffont, J.-J., 20, 13802
Korea Development Bank, 108, 111, Laissez{aire, 17, 53, 78, 88
122 Lal, D., 101, 102
Korea Heavy Industries and Lancaster, K., 9,99
Construction Company, 122, 123, Land refonn, 124
154026 Landes, D., .15In44
Korea International Steel Associates, Lange, 0., 26,72
117 Landesmann, M.: 60, 147n7
Korea Trade Organisation (KOTRA), Landsorganisationen i Sverige (LO),
145n23 137n5; see also Sweden
Kukje group, 128 Langlois, R., 34, 13708, 142n30, 144016
learning in, 118 Laski, K., 26
liberalisation in, 98-9 Late development, 81, 118; see also
macroeconomic policy in, 110-11 Catching-up
manufacturing growth in, 93, 96 Latin America, 118, 124, 155030
nature of the state in, 124 Lavoie, D., 26, 72, 139012, 142nl
politics of, 9 t, 125-7 Lawrence, R., 82, 14708
price controls in, 108, 116-17 Learning, 46, 73, 76, 89, 118, 131, 134,
production structure of, 93-7 144014, 154022
public enterprises in, 108, 127 Learning by doing, 30
push and pull factors in the structural Lee, J. M., 143011
change of, 97 Lee, S. H. (1985), 122
rent-seeking in, 117-23 Lee, S. H. (1989), 116, 117
research and development in, 116-7 Lee, Y. S., 153nl1
scale economies in, 111, 125 Legitimacy, 85-6, 134, 140020, 141027
Semaul movement in, 126 Leibenstein, H., l40n 19
shipbuilding industry in, 108, 111, 114, Leijonhufvud, A., 50
118, 122, 152n8 Leipziger, D., 111, 122
Special Laws, 113. 122 Li, Kwan Yew, 19
social structure of, 124 Liberalism, 14, 139nl1
state intervention in, 91, 97, 101, Libertarianism, 139011
108-13, 121, 155n32 Liberty, see Freedom
state intervention, porous, 107 Licensing, 40-1,67.84
state intervention, proscriptive vs. Lim, H. C., 124
prescriptive, 107-8, 154n23 Lindbeck, A., 60, 80
state intervention, self-cancelling, Linkages, 11,150n37
101-6 Lippincott, B., 72
state intervention in, efficiency of, 124 Lipsey, R., 9, 99
steel industry in, 118, 127, 153021 Liquidity, of assets, see Asset specificity
structural change in, 92, 94, 96, 97 List, F., 125
180 Index
, Little, I., 101 Mercuro, N., 29
Littlechild, S., 29-30 Merger, 69
J....obbying, 20,47, 14On18, 143n8 Merit goods, 12
Loyalty, see Organisation, loyalty to Mexico, 92, 93, 94, 103-4, 113
Luedde-Neurath, R., 98, 102, 124, 147n9, Michell, T., 109,126
152nl Milgrom, P., 40,47,48
Lundvall, B., 137n9, 142029, 151n41 Miliband, R., 20, 140n15
Luxury goods Mises, L. 10, 13, 14
controls on the imports of, 98, 152n4 Mishan, E., 138n4
the psychology of consuming, 11 Minimal state, 17, 21 ; see also
Contractarianism; Laissez-faire
Macroeconomic (in)stability, 49,54,55, Mixed economy, 1
83 Mixed strategy, 63, 143n9; see also
Maddison, A.) 92, 94 Game theory
Magaziner, I., 37,67,68,76,87, Mohammad, S., 119, 142n5
118, 137n7, 147nn9-10, 150038, Moll, T., 143n7
151n40, 152n7, 153016, 1530n18-9 Monetarism, 1, 2
Maier, C., 137n4, 146n26, 151n49 Monitoring, 26,46-7,49,51-2,68,
Malaysia, 153n16 141027, 144nI8, 146024
Mandel, E., 138n3 Monopoly, 9-10, 139nn7-8, 141n27,
Manufacturing, the importance of, 109, 142n29, 143n9
147n7 public vs. private, 10
Mao, T. S., 126 in rent-seeking, 41-2
March, 1., 35, 37 Monopoly profit, 27-8,67
Marglin, S., 1, 144n15 Morality, 12-8,23, 132
Market Morris-Suzuki, T., 125
critique on the institutional primacy of, l\1oth-balling, 69, 71; see also Capacity
132 scrapping; Exit
failure, 5, 7-12, 18,33,46, 53-4, Mueller, D., 23, 137n10, 140016
1390n 11-2, 142n30; see also Multinational corporations (MNCs), see
Government failure Korea, foreign direct investment in
forces, 89 Musgrave, P., 12, 137nl
as an institution, 4, 7, 16, 132 Musgrave, R., 12, 13701
share 69, 70 Mutation: biological vs. industrial, 73,
sharing, 70, 71, 120, 122 81; see also Evolution; Natural
Marshall, A., 4, 5 selection
Marshallian triangle, see Deadweight loss
'Marx, K., 4,5, 18,64,65,83, 121, 125, Nalebuff, B., 68
131, 141n24, 148n14, 148019, Nath, K., 11
149n28 National Economic Development Office
Marxism, 20, 21, 140020 (NEDO), 147n 1
Marxist theories of the state, 18, 138n3, Nationalisation, see Public enterprises;
139n15 Korea, bank nationalisation in
Mason, E., 108 Natural selection, 57, 64, 73-4; see also
Matthews, R., 49, 137n8, 144nn13-19 Evolution; Mutation
Maynard Smith, J., 63, 64 Negotiated exit, see Exit; Capacity
McCormick, R., 140n16 scrapping: Moth-balling; Recession
McLellan, D., 146n25 cartel
McNulty, P., 148013 Neighbourhood effects, 12, 15
McPherson, M., 15,23, 132 Nelson, R., 61, 74, 77, 78,83, 137n9,
Measurement costs, 47-8 139n9, 150n31
Meiji Restoration, see Japan, Meiji Neoclassical economics, 46, 101,
Restoration in 139n16, 156n2
Index 181
Neoclassical Political Economy, 18, Pareto efficiency, 7
139n16 Park Chung Hee, 108, 125, 155n31; see
Network externalities, 51, 74; see also also Korea, politics of
System scale economies Park, Y., 99. 127, 152n5
New Institutional Economics, 4, 5, 6, 13, Parker, G., 64
15,53-4, 142030,I44nI6 Patents, 30,40,47, 76,84
and transaction costs, 49-50 Patenaalism, 12-14; see also
New Political Economy, see Neoclassical Contractarianism
Political Economy Peacock, A., 8, 10, 14, 139nl1, 14On19
New Right, 2, 137n3 Pecuniary externalities, 11; see also
Newly Industrialising Countries (NICs), Externalities
1,3,93 Pekkarinen, J., 137n4
Nirvana state, 46, 48 Pelikan, P., 149n29
Niskanen, W., 22 Peltzman, S., 20
Non-competitive markets, 9-10, 138n6, Perfect competition
13908 Hayek's critique of the notion of,
Non-excludability, 8, 138n2; see also 62-3
Public goods Demsetz's nirvana state and, 47
Non-rivalness in consumption, 8, 138n2; perfect decentralisation and, 82
see also Public Goods Peters, R., 102
Norms, 50-1, 140018 Philosopher King, 18
North, D 18, 19,21,49,52, 79,83, 131, Picking the winner, 39, 73, 80, 81; see
144n16 also Industrial policy
Norton, R., 137n6,14704 Pinder, l, 58, 147n3
Nozick, R., 13, 16, 17 Plan contracts, 37, 82; see also France,
industrial policy in
O'Connor, J., 140n20 Planning, see Central planning; Indicative
O'Driscoll, G., 148n13 planning
Oakland, W., 138n2 Planning debate, 26, 72, 139012, 142nl
Oil shock, 1, 93 Poggi, G., 16, 19,23
Okiomoto, D., 67,69,76,81,13707, Polanyi, K., 16,49, 132
147n9, 148n20 Policing costs, 47-8
Oligarchy, 41 Political economy, 18-32,43,45, 146029
Oligopoly, 65, 139n9, 142n29, 14309 Political entrepreneurs, and collective
Olson, M., 8,9,20, 138n2 action, 9; see also Collective action
Olympian rationality, see Rationality problem
Order: spontaneous vs. constructed, 131 Political market, 20-2, 29
Organisation for Economic Cooperation Politics, 21, 44-5, 85-9
and Development (OEeD), 5-6 Pontusson, J., 137n4
Organisation Poor Law, 16-17
design of, 37 Popkin, S., 9
as a device to deal with complexity and Porous state intervention, see Korea, state
uncertainty, 34, 52 intervention, porous
and the fallacy of composition, 34 Porter, M., 52, 76, 146n28, 150035
loyalty to, 23-4, 27, 37 Posner, R., 28,29
decision-nlakiog structure of, 35-7 Power, 7, 22, 40
Over-investment, see Investment Predatory state, 18-9, 25; see also State
coordination Preference, 11, 21, 51
counteradaptive, 11
Pagano, U., 62,64,65, 131, 132, 13708, endogenous preference formation, 24
144015, 148n15 interdependence of preferences, 11
Paik, N. K., 112, 153n20, 156036 preference for preferences, 16
Panitch, L., 137n4, 151n45 Price control, see Korea, price controls in
182 Index
Price wars, 66-8 Olympian vs. bounded, 34-5
Price, V 0' 80 substantive vs. procedural, 34-5
Principal-agent problem, 24, 26-7, 82; Rawls, Jo, 13
see also Agency costs; Infonnatioo, Recession cartel, 59,67-71
asymmetric Reciprocity, 140-1 n21 ; see also
Priority sectors, 110- 11, 112-114, Cooperation
154023; see also Korea, industrial Regulation, 20,61, 114-15, ]31
policy in Regulatory capture, 20, 39
Private costs and benefits, see Costs and Reich, R., 56, 58
benefits Rejuvenation, of industries, 150n39
Private goods, 8,40, 13802; see also Relative prices, 102; see also Korea,
Public goods incentive neutrality in and trade
Private sector, 133 policy in
Process-orientation, 139011 Relocation, of industries, 77
Product cycle, 76-7, 134, 141n40, Renshaw, Jo, 55,149n22
150nn38-9 Rent-seeking, 25, 33, 38-45, 82-4,
Production costs, 46-8, 66, 144018 142un24-7, 142n5, 143n6,
Productive vSo unproductive activities, see 143009-10, 143n12
Rent-seeking; Entrepreneurship, bystander effect in, 39
productive and unproductive collective action problem in, 38, 40-]
Productivity, growth of, 30-1,45,56-8, competitiveness of, 41-4
67-8,83,135 competitive politics vs. competive
Property, 15 markets, 30,44-5
Property rights, 5-6, 18,24,47-9,54,85, costs of, 27
131-3 definition of, 27
and externalities, 11 monopolistic, 27, 41
instituting, 49 entry barriers to, 41-3,45
protection Qf, 15 oligopolistic, 41-3
and public goods, 8, 138n2 productive vs. unproductive, 20, 30-1,
Protection, see Korea, trade policy 82-4
Public choice, 140n16 second-tier, 43-4, 119
Public enterprises, 142n4; in Korea, Rents, 44
108, 127 state-created, 27-31,38-45, 83-4,
Public goods, 8-9 118-19,120-1,123,145020
collective action problem and, 8--9, 15, see also Monopoly profit; Rent-seeking
40, 138n2, 13804 Research and development (R&D), 30,
definition of, 8 . 44,47,59,78,84, 148n17, 149027
see also Private goods Resource allocation, 48
Public sector, see Public enterprises Restrictive practices, 44; see also
Puttennao, Lo, 13708, 144n 16 Collusion; Schumpeter
Restructuring: industrial, see Industrial
QWERTY, 75 restructuring
Retraining, 77
Ranis, Go, 98, 15202 Returns to scale, 62-3
Rasiah, Ro, 153015 Revolution, 23; constitutional, 29, 31
Rasmusen, Ro, 63 Richardson, Go B., 62, 65, 66, 70, 75, 80,
Rationalisation, 114, 115, 117; see also 84, 121, 131, 137n8, 149n26,
Korea, industrial policy in; Japan, 150n37
industrial policy in Rights, 13,47, 49, 131; see also Property
Rationality rights
bounded, 27,34-5,46,49,71, 144n16 Rigidities, 2, 3
different notions of, 34-5, 142n1 Risk, see Socialisation of risk
individual vSo collective, 8, 27~8 Robbins, L., 46
Index 183
Roberts, J., 40,47,48 Skilled workforce, 58, 60, 118
Rogerson, W., 14309 Skocpol, T.~ 19-21
Role of the state, see State Small firms, 59, 125
Rosenberg, N., 72, 73, 79, 137n9, Small number competition, 42, 63; see
144n14, 149n30, 150039, 153014, also Oligopoly
154n22 Smith, A., 4, 5, 131
Rowley, C., 10, 14, 139011, 141n22 Social contract, 31; see also
Rowthom, B., 3, 57, 13704, 13802, Contractarianism
144n18, 14702, 15601 Social corporatism, 2-3,52, 13704,
151049
Sachs, J., 124, 137n4 Social costs and benefits, see Costs and
Sakoog, I., 108,114, 126~ 13707, 147n9, benefits, private vs. social
152nl Socialisation of risk, 6, 42, 78-9, 89,
Salter, W., 69 134
Samuels, W., 29 Socialism, 14
Samuelson, P., 13802 Soete, L., 77
Savings, 59, 60, 98, 99, 109 South Africa, 94, 103-4
Savings gap, 109, 112 South Korea, see Korea
Schelling, T, 34, 39,43,53, 120 Soviet Union, 53
Schor, J., 1 Spain, 93, 103-4
Schott, K., 24, 13704, 137nl0 Specific assets, see Asset specificity
Schotter, A., 8, 11, 13,50-1, 13701 Spontaneous coordination, 61
Schultze, C., 152n50 Spontaneous order, 131; see also Order
Schumpeter, J., 70, 73, 79,82-3, 121, State
125, 137n9, 141024, 149n28 abdication of power by, 39
Scitovsky, T., 11 agenda formation and, 20-1
Second best, theory of, 9, 10,99 autonomous, 18, 19, 31
Selection, see Natural selection benevolent, 22, 39
Selective incentives, 9,21; see also failures of, see Government failure
Collective action problem hard, 25
Selective industrial policy, see Industrial monopolisation of violence by, 49
policy, general vs. selective predatory, 23, 39
Self-interest, 22-4, 140n16, 140-In16 roie of, 33, 52, 54, 55, 78, 132
and organisational loyalty, 37 self-cancelling, 101-4
see also Altruism vulnerability of, 38-40, 86
Self-seeking bureaucrats, 18, 22-4, 31, State intervention, 16, 29, 33, 48, 53-4,
142023; see also Budget 55,70,81
maximisation New Institutionalist theory of, 45-54
Semaul (New Village) Movement, see porous, 107
Korea, Semaul Movement prescriptive vs. proscriptive, 107-8,
Sen, A., 34 154n23
Service sector, 56-8 transaction costs and, 48-54
Shapiro, H., 155030 Static efficiency, 46, 72, 77, 101; see also
Shepherd, G., 14703 Efficiency
Shepsle, K., 14On16 Stigler, G., 5, 11,20, 150n33
Shortages: in socialist economies, 26 Stiglitz, J., 26, 13701, 138n2
Side paynlents, 120, 148-9nn21-2; see Stinchombe, A., 80
also Game theory Stout, D., 147nl
Signalling, 76, 141-2n27, 146n28 Strategic behaviour, 8
Simon, H. 24,27,34-7,49,133, 137n8, Strategic industry, 110,127
141n21, 142n2, 149n24 Structural change, 10, 57; see also Korea,
Singapore, 1, 19,92-3, 153015 structural change· in
Singh, A., 139n8, 14702, 155n30 Structuralism, 21
184 Index
Sub-goal identification, 35-7; see also Under-investment, see Investment
Infonnation, localised vs. global coordination
Subcontracting, 49 United Kingdom (UK), 56,84,87,89,
Subsidies, 20, 76, 78, 84, 101 117, 137n3
Supply-side economics, 2 United States of America (USA), 39, 52,
Svennilson, I., 73 56,117, 149n30, 150n35
Sweden, 3, 88 Untraded interdependence, 11; see also
System scale econorrries, 51; see also Externalities
Network externalities Upgrading, 109,112,117,121