Textbook Agent Based Models in Economics A Toolkit Domenico Delli Gatti Ebook All Chapter PDF
Textbook Agent Based Models in Economics A Toolkit Domenico Delli Gatti Ebook All Chapter PDF
Textbook Agent Based Models in Economics A Toolkit Domenico Delli Gatti Ebook All Chapter PDF
https://textbookfull.com/product/fuzzy-models-in-economics-
gorkhmaz-imanov/
https://textbookfull.com/product/equilibrium-models-in-economics-
purposes-and-critical-limitations-1st-edition-lawrence-a-boland/
https://textbookfull.com/product/innovative-approaches-in-agent-
based-modelling-and-business-intelligence-setsuya-kurahashi/
Agent-Based Modelling and Network Dynamics 1st Edition
Chen
https://textbookfull.com/product/agent-based-modelling-and-
network-dynamics-1st-edition-chen/
https://textbookfull.com/product/a-python-data-analysts-toolkit-
learn-python-and-python-based-libraries-with-applications-in-
data-analysis-and-statistics-gayathri-rajagopalan/
https://textbookfull.com/product/towards-a-competence-based-view-
on-models-and-modeling-in-science-education-annette-upmeier-zu-
belzen/
https://textbookfull.com/product/agent-based-modelling-of-social-
networks-in-labour-education-market-system-1st-edition-alexander-
tarvid-auth/
https://textbookfull.com/product/modern-approaches-to-agent-
based-complex-automated-negotiation-1st-edition-katsuhide-fujita/
Agent-Based Models in Economics
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:49:57, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
affiliate of Collegio Carlo Alberto, Torino. An internationally recognised scholar in
both agent-based and dynamic microsimulation modelling, he has also worked as a
consultant on labour market policies for the World Bank. He is Chief Editor of the
International Journal of Microsimulation, and project leader of JAS-mine, an open
source simulation platform for discrete event simulations (www.jas-mine.net).
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:49:57, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Agent-Based Models in Economics
A Toolkit
Edited by
D O M E N I C O D E L L I G AT T I
Catholic University of the Sacred Heart
G I O R G I O FAG I O L O
Sant’Anna School of Advanced Studies
M AU RO G A L L E G AT I
Marche Polytechnic University
M AT T E O R I C H I A R D I
University of Torino
A L B E RTO RU S S O
Marche Polytechnic University
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:49:57, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
University Printing House, Cambridge CB2 8BS, United Kingdom
One Liberty Plaza, 20th Floor, New York, NY 10006, USA
477 Williamstown Road, Port Melbourne, VIC 3207, Australia
314–321, 3rd Floor, Plot 3, Splendor Forum, Jasola District Centre,
New Delhi – 110025, India
79 Anson Road, #06–04/06, Singapore 079906
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781108414999
DOI: 10.1017/9781108227278
© Cambridge University Press 2018
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2018
Printed in the United Kingdom by Clays, St Ives plc
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Delli Gatti, Domenico, editor.
Title: Agent-based models in economics : a toolkit / edited by
Domenico Delli Gatti [and four others].
Description: Cambridge, United Kingdom ; New York, NY :
Cambridge University Press, [2017] |
Includes bibliographical references and index.
Identifiers: LCCN 2017042298 | ISBN 9781108414999 (Hardback : alk. paper) |
ISBN 9781108400046 (Paperback : alk. paper)
Subjects: LCSH: Econometric models. | Economics–Mathematical models.
Classification: LCC HB141 .A3185 2017 | DDC 330.01/5195–dc23
LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2017042298
ISBN 978-1-108-41499-9 Hardback
ISBN 978-1-108-40004-6 Paperback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy
of URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:49:57, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
To our heterogeneous most relevant ones.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:53:10, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
An important scientific innovation rarely makes its way by
gradually winning over and converting its opponents:
What does happen is that the opponents gradually die out.
(Max Planck)
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:53:10, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Contents
1 Introduction 1
1.1 Hard Times for Dr Pangloss 1
1.2 The Complexity View 3
1.3 Heterogeneity in a Neoclassical World 4
1.4 Agent-Based Models (ABMs) 6
1.5 Plan of the Book 8
vii
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:55:00, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
viii Contents
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:55:00, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Contents ix
5.3 Learning 93
5.3.1 Individual Learning 1: Statistical Learning 95
5.3.2 Individual Learning 2: Fitness Learning 97
5.3.3 Social Learning 105
5.3.4 Individual vs. Social Learning 107
5.4 Conclusions 108
6 Interaction 109
6.1 Introduction 109
6.2 Modeling Interactions 110
6.2.1 Local Exogenous Interaction 114
6.2.2 Endogenous Interaction 118
6.3 Networks: Basic Concepts and Properties 125
6.4 Static and Dynamic Networks 133
6.4.1 Static Networks 133
6.4.2 Dynamic Networks 137
6.5 Conclusions 141
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:55:00, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
x Contents
10 Epilogue 222
Bibliography 224
Index 240
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:55:00, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Figures
xi
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:57:15, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
xii Figures
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:57:15, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Tables
xiii
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:59:15, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Contributors
Domenico Delli Gatti (Catholic University of the Sacred Heart, Milan, Italy)
is Professor of Economics at Catholic University of the Sacred Heart, from
which he received his PhD in 1987. His research interests focus on the role of
financial factors (firms’ and banks’ financial fragility) in business
fluctuations, a field he started exploring in collaboration with Hyman Minsky
in the late 1980s and revisited in a new light due to the research work carried
out with Joe Stiglitz and Bruce Greenwald since the 1990s. He has been a
visiting scholar to several universities, including Stanford, Massachusetts
Institute of Technology and Columbia. He was previously the editor of the
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization and is currently the editor of
the Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination. Recently he has
devoted his research effort to two areas of research: the first one concerns the
properties of multi-agent models characterised by “financial frictions”; the
second area concerns the properties of networks in borrowing-lending
relationships.
xiv
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 19:01:05, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
List of Contributors xv
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 19:01:05, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
xvi List of Contributors
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 19:01:05, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278
Preface
xvii
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 19:02:10, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.001
xviii Preface
The current predicament, both in the real world and in the public debate,
resembles the early 1930s. The way out of the Great Depression required a
new economic theory and the Second World War.1 Luckily, in order to escape
the current predicament, we can dispense at least with the latter. We still need,
however, to reshape the way in which we think about the economy.
For several years now, a complexity approach has been developed which
conceives the economy as a complex system of heterogeneous interacting
agents characterised by limited information and bounded rationality. In this
view, a ‘crisis’ is a macroscopic phenomenon which spontaneously emerges
from the web of microscopic interactions. Agent-Based Models (ABMs) are
the analytical and computational tools necessary to explore the properties of a
complex economy.
Agent-based macroeconomics is still in its infancy, but it is undoubtedly a
very promising line of research. So far only a small minority in the economic
profession has adopted this approach. This may be due to the wait-and-
see attitude of those who want to see the approach well established in the
profession before embracing it. The hesitation, however, may also come from
methodological conservatism. For instance, while in other disciplines the
explanatory power of computer simulations is increasingly recognized, most
economists remain dismissive of any scientific work that is not based on strict
mathematical proof.2 With the passing of years, however, agent-based (AB)
tools have been refined. This book is a guide to the main issues which an
interested reader may encounter when approaching this field. We hope this will
help in nudging a new generation of curious minds to explore the fascinating
field of complexity.
We thank for comments, criticisms and insightful conversations Tiziana
Assenza, Leonardo Bargigli, Alessandro Caiani, Alberto Cardaci, Ermanno
Catullo, Eugenio Caverzasi, Annarita Colasante, Giovanni Dosi, Lisa Gian-
moena, Federico Giri, Jakob Grazzini, Bruce Greenwald, Ruggero Grilli, Alan
Kirman, Roberto Leombruni, Simone Landini, Domenico Massaro, Mauro
Napoletano, Antonio Palestrini, Luca Riccetti, Andrea Roventini, Joe Stiglitz,
Leigh Tesfatstion.
This book benefited from funding from the European Community’s
Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007–2013), INET, CRISIS, NESS, and
MATHEMACS.
1
The unemployment rate, which peaked at 1/4 of the labour force during the Great Depression,
went back to the long-run ‘normal’ of around 1/20 only after the end of the war. The huge
increase in government spending due to the war effort helped to absorb the unemployment
2
generated by the Great Depression.
A recent intriguing line of research aims at providing analytical solutions to multi-agent
systems adopting the apparatus of statistical mechanics, e.g., the Fokker-Planck equations.
See, for instance, M. Aoki (2011), Di Guilmi (2016).
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 19:02:10, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.001
1
Introduction
Domenico Delli Gatti and Mauro Gallegati
1
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
2 Domenico Delli Gatti and Mauro Gallegati
The latter differs from the former because of the presence of imperfections,
the most important being imperfect competition and nominal rigidity. The
structural form of the standard NK-DSGE framework boils down to a three-
equation model consisting of an optimising IS equation, an NK Phillips curve
and a monetary policy rule based on changes in the interest rate.
The NK-DSGE framework is, of course, too simple and therefore inadequate
to analyse the emergence of a financial crisis and a major recession for the very
good reason that neither asset prices nor measures of agents, financial fragility
show up anywhere in the model. In order to make the model operational from
this viewpoint, financial frictions have been incorporated into the basic model
in one way or another.
In the last decade we have witnessed an explosion of models with these
types of frictions. The story that can be attached to this literature, however,
can be told in simple terms. A negative shock triggers a recession and yields
a reduction of firms’ internally generated funds. Borrowers need more funds,
but lenders are less willing to supply loans as the value of firms’ collateral is
also going down. Hence, firms might be forced to scale activity down. This in
turn will lead to lower cash flow, and to a further deceleration of activity.
The financial accelerator provides a mechanism of amplification of an
aggregate shock (i.e., a positive feedback or a self-reinforcing mechanism)
based on financial factors. By construction, however, it cannot be a model of
the origin of a financial crisis and the ensuing recession.
As in all DSGE models, in fact, in models characterised by financial
frictions a fluctuation is also determined by an aggregate shock (an impulse)
and is channeled to the economy by a propagation mechanism. Moreover,
the stability of the steady state makes fluctuations persistent but relatively
short lived. Therefore, a great recession may be explained only by a sizable
aggregate negative shock and is bound to disappear relatively soon. Recent
models incorporating financial frictions trace back the great recession to
a major negative shock (possibly of a new type: an ‘investment shock’, a
‘financial shock’ instead of the usual Total Factor Productivity shock) which
spreads through the economy and becomes persistent because of the financial
amplification, but is temporary so that the economy goes back to equilibrium
in due time.
This view of the Global Financial Crisis is not convincing. It does not
provide a plausible theory of its origin, since the crisis was not the conse-
quence of a global shock, but originated from a small segment of the US
financial system (the subprime loans market) and spread to the entire US
financial system and to the world economy. Moreover, it does not provide an
appropriate characterisation of the actual recovery, which has been unusually
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
Introduction 3
long and painful.1 In fact, during the recession, quantitative forecasts of future
GDP growth (also at a very short-time horizon) generated by these models
systematically overestimated actual GDP growth.
The financial accelerator story is intriguing, but is not enough to characterise
a major crisis. Models with financial frictions yield interesting results, but
their scope is necessarily limited because of the built-in features of the DSGE
framework. This framework, in fact, abstracts from the complex web of
financial and real relationships among heterogeneous agents that characterise
modern financially sophisticated economies and are at the root of the spreading
of financial fragility economywide. Contemporary macroeconomics, in other
words, has assumed away most of the features of the economy which are
relevant today.
1
The idea of a ‘secular stagnation’ pioneered by L. Summers, which is gaining ground in the
profession, is based exactly on the unusual length and painfulness of the recovery from the
Great Recession.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
4 Domenico Delli Gatti and Mauro Gallegati
2
As Max Planck put it: ‘Normal science does not aim at novelties of fact or theory and, when
3
successful, finds none.’
One possible way is to keep the number of agents low, i.e., to reduce the dimensionality of the
problem (two types of agents). An example, among many, is the NK-DSGE framework with
Limited Asset Market Participation, where households can be either free to access financial
markets or financially constrained. In the latter case, households cannot smooth consumption
4
by borrowing and lending.
These models are also known as Bewley models (according to the terminology proposed by
Ljungqvist, 2004) or Standard Incomplete Markets models (Heathcote, 2009). Notice that
Heterogeneous Agents and Incomplete Market go hand-in-hand, for reasons which will
become clear momentarily.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
Introduction 5
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
6 Domenico Delli Gatti and Mauro Gallegati
higher moments of the distribution can be safely ignored and one can think
of the economy as if it were a Representative Agent world, identified with the
Average Agent.
Agents in a Krusell-Smith economy are ‘near rational’ as they optimise
using only the moments of the distribution. Forming near rational expectations
of future prices in such an environment is a daunting but not impossible task,
as equilibrium prices are functions only of the moments of the distribution
instead of the entire distribution.
In this model there is approximate aggregation: ‘in equilibrium all aggregate
variables . . . can be almost perfectly described as a function of two simple
statistics: the mean of the wealth distribution and the aggregate productivity
shock’ (Krusell and Smith, 1998, p. 869). Using only these measures, near-
rational agents are able to minimise the forecast errors (therefore higher
moments of the distribution do not affect the decision of the agents).
Moreover, Krusell and Smith show through simulations that macroeconomic
time series generated by the model are almost indistinguishable from those
generated by a Representative Agent model. Hence macroeconomic fluctuation
can be sufficiently described by fluctuation of the mean; higher moments
of the distribution do not add much to the picture. In other words, taking
heterogeneity on board does not add much to the accuracy of the model. Only
the first moment of the distribution has macroeconomic consequences. In a
sense, this is a very smart way of resurrecting the moribund Representative
Agent and the macroeconomic literature based on it.
However, as shown by Heathcote (2009), with reference to fiscal shocks,
there are indeed real-world circumstances in which heterogeneity has impor-
tant macroeconomic consequences, even in Neoclassical multiagent models.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
Introduction 7
7
In principle, however, behavioural rules can be either grounded in bounded rationality (rules of
thumb) or can be derived from specific optimization problems (optimal rules).
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
8 Domenico Delli Gatti and Mauro Gallegati
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
Introduction 9
through monetarist, New Classical and New Keynesian models. This survey
allows us to put the AB methodology into context and paves the way to
the more detailed analysis of behavioural rules and learning processes in
Chapter 5.
Chapter 5, in fact, digs deeper into the definition and description of the
agent’s rationality and learning processes. Where do behavioural rules come
from? Agents in real economies are intentional subjects. In order to decide
on a line of action (a behavioural rule), in fact, they must form mental
representations of their environment and of the behaviour of other agents.
Behavioural rules in the real world, therefore, must be related to the cognitive
processes that guide actions. Learning is a key ingredient of these cognitive
processes.
Chapter 6 deals with the issue of interaction, which is key in ABMs. In
a sense, the chapter is an introductory overview of network theory, a rapidly
expanding field both in mainstream and complexity theory. ABMs, in fact, are
often based on an underlying network structure, e.g., of trading relationships,
credit relationships, supply chain, etc.
Chapter 7 explores the research outcome of an ABM, i.e., the model
behaviour. The AB researcher, in fact, sets up the ‘rules of the game’ – i.e.,
she builds the model – but does not know in advance the implications of those
rules, e.g., the statistical structure of the output of simulations. The chapter
presents techniques to gain understanding about the model behaviour – the
Data Generating Process implicit in the ABM – which are quite underexplored
in the AB literature. In a model which requires simulations, only inductive
knowledge about its behaviour can be gained, by repeatedly running the model
under different samples from the parameter space.
Chapter 8 is devoted to the empirical validation of ABMs. Empirically
validating an ABM means, broadly speaking, ‘taking the model to the data’,
essentially in the form of empirical and/or experimental data. Validation may
concern the model inputs and/or outputs. Input validation is essentially the
assessment of the ‘realism’ of the assumptions on which the model rests while
output validation is the assessment of the capability of the model to replicate
in artificial or simulated data the stylised facts of economic reality under
consideration. Output validation is a joint test on the structure of the model
and the values of the parameters. This means that input and output validation
are connected.
Chapters 9 deals with the issue of estimation of ABM parameters, an
intriguing new field which aims to align the empirical validation techniques
of ABMs to that of standard macroeconomic models where estimation tools
are readily available and relatively easy to implement.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:35:01, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.002
2
Agent-Based Computational Economics:
What, Why, When
Matteo Richiardi
2.1 Introduction
What are agent-based (AB) models? In a nutshell, they are models (i.e.,
abstract representations of the reality) in which (i) a multitude of objects inter-
act with each other and with the environment, (ii) the objects are autonomous
(i.e., there is no central, or “top-down,” control over their behavior and, more
generally, on the dynamics of the system)1 , and (iii) the outcome of their
interaction is numerically computed. Since the objects are autonomous, they
are called agents. The application of agent-based modeling to economics is
called Agent-Based Computational Economics (ACE). As Leigh Tesfatsion –
one of the leading researchers in the field and the “mother” of the ACE
acronym – defines it, ACE is
the computational study of economic processes modeled as dynamic systems of
interacting agents (Tesfatsion, 2006).
1
The Walrasian auctioneer, for instance, is a top-down device for ensuring market clearing.
Another example of top-down control is the consistency-of-expectations requirement typically
introduced by the modeler in order to allow for a meaningful equilibrium in neoclassical
models. More on this point on Section 2.2 below.
10
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:36:40, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.003
Agent-Based Computational Economics: What, Why, When 11
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. Access paid by the UCSB Libraries, on 08 Mar 2018 at 18:36:40, subject to the
Cambridge Core terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108227278.003
Another random document with
no related content on Scribd:
576.
Tabari, i. c. lxxix.; Abulfeda, p. 35.
577.
Rabboth, fol. 302 b; Devarim Rabba, fol. 246, col. 2.
578.
Weil, pp. 188, 189.
579.
Weil, p. 190.
580.
Rabboth, fol. 302 b.
581.
Weil, pp. 190, 191.
582.
Lyra Anglicana, London, 1864, “The Burial of Moses.”
583.
Talmud, Tract. Sota, fol. 14 a.
584.
Tabari, i. p. 396.
585.
Talmud of Jerusalem; Tract. Terumoth.
586.
Josh. vii. 1-5.
587.
Tabari, i. p. 402.
588.
Koran, Sura ii. v. 55, 56.
589.
Tabari, p. 404.
590.
Tabari, p. 401.
591.
Ibid. p. 404.
592.
Berescheth Rabba.
593.
The Mussulmans say Khasqîl or Ezechiel.
594.
Judges i. 4.
595.
Tabari, i. p. 404.
596.
Eisenmenger, i. p. 395.
597.
Hist. Dynast. p. 24.
598.
Tabari, i. c. lxxxvii.
599.
D’Herbelot, Bibl. Orient., s. v. Aschmouil.
600.
Koran, Sura ii. v. 247, 248.
601.
Koran, Sura ii. v. 248.
602.
D’Herbelot, Bib. Orientale, t. i. p. 263.
603.
Tabari, i. p. 417.
604.
This incident, from the apocryphal gospels of the childhood of
Christ, shall be related in the Legendary Lives of New
Testament Characters.
605.
Weil, pp. 193-8.
606.
Koran, Sura ii. v. 250.
607.
Tabari, i. p. 418.
608.
Perhaps the passage in Psalm cvii. 35 may refer to this
miracle, unrecorded in Holy Scripture.
609.
Weil, pp. 200, 201.
610.
Koran, Sura ii. v. 251.
612.
Tabari, i. p. 421.
613.
Ibid.
614.
Tabari, i. p. 422; Weil, pp. 202-4; D’Herbelot, i. p. 362.
615.
Weil, pp. 205-8.
616.
Tabari, i. p. 423. The same story is told of the escape of S.
Felix of Nola, in the Decian persecution.
617.
Tabari, i. p. 429.
618.
Weil, p. 207.
619.
Tabari, i. p. 424.
620.
Ps. li. 5.
621.
Midrash, fol. 204, col. 1.
622.
Ps. cxviii. 22.
623.
See the story in the Legends of Adam.
624.
Zohar, in Bartolocci, i. fol. 85, col. 2.
625.
Jalkut, fol. 32, col. 2 (Parasch 2, numb. 134).
626.
Ibid. (Parasch. 2, numb. 127).
627.
1 Sam. xvii. 43.
628.
2 Sam. iii. 29.
629.
Zohar, in Bartolocci, i. fol. 99, col. 1.
630.
Talmud, Tract. Sanhedrim, fol. 107.
631.
1 Kings ii. 11.
632.
2 Sam. v. 5.
633.
Bartolocci, i. f. 100.
634.
1 Sam. xxiv. 4.
635.
Bartolocci, i. f. 122, col. 1.
636.
1 Kings i. 1.
637.
Bartolocci, i. f. 122, col. 2.
638.
Ps. lvii. 9; Bartolocci, i. fol. 125, col. 2.
639.
Talmud, Tract. Sota, fol. 10 b.
640.
Ps. xxii. 21.
641.
Midrash Tillim, fol. 21, col. 2.
642.
Eisenmenger, i. p. 409.
643.
Ps. xviii. 36.
644.
Ps. lv. 6.
645.
Ps. lxviii. 13.
646.
Talmud, Tract. Sanhedrim, fol. 95, col. 1.
647.
Tract. Sabbath, fol. 30, col. 2.
648.
Tabari, i. p. 426; Weil, p. 208.
649.
Weil, p. 207.
650.
Tabari, p. 428.
651.
The Arabs call her Saga.
652.
The story in the Talmud is almost the same, with this
difference: Bathsheba was washing herself behind a beehive,
then the beautiful bird perched on the hive, and David shot an
arrow at it and broke the hive, and exposed Bathsheba to view.
In the Rabbinic tale, David had asked for the gift of prophecy,
and God told him he must be tried. This he agreed to, and the
temptation to adultery was that sent him. (Talmud, Tract.
Sanhedrim, fol. 107, col. 2; Jalkut, fol. 22, col. 2.)
653.
Koran, Sura xxxviii.
654.
Weil, pp. 212, 213.
655.
Weil, pp. 213-224.
656.
Greek text, and Latin translation in Fabricius: Pseudigr. Vet.
Test. t. ii. pp. 905-7.
657.
;סגולות ורפואותAmst. 1703.
658.
Solomon was twelve years old when he succeeded David.
(Abulfeda, p. 43; Bartolocci, iv. p. 371.)
659.
Weil, pp. 225-231; Eisenmenger, p. 440, &c.
660.
Weil, pp. 231-4.
661.
The story of the building of the temple, with the assistance of
Schamir, has been already related by me in my “Curious Myths
of the Middle Ages.”
662.
The Rabbinic story and the Mussulman are precisely the same,
with the difference that Benaiah, the son of Jehoiada, instead
of the Jinns, lies in ambush and captures Sachr or Aschmedai
(Asmodeus). (Eisenmenger, i. 351-8.) As I have given the
Jewish version in my “Curious Myths of the Middle Ages,” I
give the Arab story here.
663.
Weil, pp. 234-7; Talmud, Tract. Gittin. fol. 68, cols. 1, 2.
664.
Jalkut Schimoni, fol. 90, col. 4.
665.
Tabari, i. p. 435.
666.
Tabari, i. p. 436.
667.
Koran, Sura xxvii.; Tabari, i. c. xcviii.; Weil, pp. 237-9.
668.
The Jews also believed in a purgatory; see Bartolocci, i. 342.
669.
Targum Scheni Esther, fol. 401, tells the same of the moorcock.
670.
This is the letter according to Rabbinic authors: “Greeting to
thee and to thine; from me, King Solomon. It is known to thee
that the holy, ever-blessed God has made me lord and king
over the wild beasts and birds of heaven, and over the devils,
and spirits, and ghosts of the night, and that all kings, from the
rising to the down-setting of the sun, come and greet me. If
thou also wilt come and salute me, then will I show thee great
honour above all the kings that lie prostrate before me. But if
thou wilt not come, and wilt not salute me, then will I send
kings, and soldiers, and horsemen against thee. And if thou
sayest in thine heart, ‘Hath King Solomon kings, and soldiers,
and horsemen?’ then know that the wild beasts are his kings,
and soldiers, and horsemen. And if thou sayest, ‘What, then,
are his horsemen?’ know that the birds of heaven are his
horsemen. His army are ghosts, and devils, and spectres of the
night; and they shall torment and slay you at night in your beds,
and the wild beasts will rend you in the fields, and the birds will
tear the flesh off you.” This letter, the Jews say, was sent to the
Queen of Sheba by a moorcock. (Targum Scheni Esther, fol.
401, 440.)
671.
According to another account, “that she had ass’s legs” (Weil,
p. 267). Tabari says, “hairy legs” (i. p. 441).
672.
Weil, pp. 246-267; Tabari, i. cc. 94, 95.
673.
Weil, pp. 267-9.
674.
Tabari, i. c. xcvi. p. 448.
675.
Weil, pp. 269-271; Tabari, pp. 450, 451.
676.
Koran, Sura xxxviii.
677.
Tabari, pp. 460, 461.
678.
In the Jewish legend, Asmodeus. In “Curiosities of Olden
Times” I have pointed out the connection between the story of
the disgrace of Solomon and that of Nebuchadnezzar,
Jovinian, Robert of Sicily, &c.
679.
Deut. xvii. 16, 17.
680.
Emek Nammelek, fol. 14; Gittin, fol. 68, col. 2; Eisenmenger, i.
pp. 358-60. The Anglo-Saxon story of Havelock the Dane
bears a strong resemblance to this part of the story of
Solomon.
681.
Eisenmenger, i. pp. 358-60; Weil, pp. 271-4; Tabari, c. 96.
682.
Weil, p. 274.
683.
Eisenmenger, i. 361.
684.
Tabari, p. 454.
685.
Koran, Sura xxxiv.; Tabari, c. 97; Weil, p. 279.
686.
Tabari, i. c. 84.
687.
Das Buch der Sagen und Legenden jüdischer Vorzeit, p. 45;
Stuttgart, 1845.
688.
Herbelot, Bibl. Orient., s. v. Zerib, iii. p. 607.
689.
Gemara, Avoda Sara, c. i. fol. 65.
690.
Anabasticon, iv. 2-12.
691.
Anabasticon, v. 1-14.
692.
Tract. Jebammoth, c. 4.
693.
Exod. xxxiii. 20.
694.
Isai. vi. 1.
695.
Deut. iv. 7.
696.
Isai. lv. 6.
697.
Tabari, i. c. 83.
698.
Bartolocci, i. p. 848.
699.
Sura, ii.
700.
Herbelot, Bibliothèque Orientale, iii. p. 89.
701.
Abulfaraj, p. 57.
702.
Hist. Eccles. lib. ix. cap. ult.
703.
Ibid., lib. xiv. c. 8.
Transcriber’s Notes:
Footnotes have been collected at the end of the text, and are
linked for ease of reference.
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK LEGENDS OF
OLD TESTAMENT CHARACTERS, FROM THE TALMUD AND
OTHER SOURCES ***
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside
the United States, check the laws of your country in addition to
the terms of this agreement before downloading, copying,
displaying, performing, distributing or creating derivative works
based on this work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The
Foundation makes no representations concerning the copyright
status of any work in any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if
you provide access to or distribute copies of a Project
Gutenberg™ work in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or
other format used in the official version posted on the official
Project Gutenberg™ website (www.gutenberg.org), you must, at
no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a copy, a
means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy upon
request, of the work in its original “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other
form. Any alternate format must include the full Project
Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.