Mazzucato 16 - From Market Fixing To Market Creating A New Framework For Innovation Policy

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

Industry and Innovation

ISSN: 1366-2716 (Print) 1469-8390 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/ciai20

From market fixing to market-creating: a new


framework for innovation policy

Mariana Mazzucato

To cite this article: Mariana Mazzucato (2016) From market fixing to market-creating:
a new framework for innovation policy, Industry and Innovation, 23:2, 140-156, DOI:
10.1080/13662716.2016.1146124

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2016.1146124

Published online: 13 May 2016.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 2467

View Crossmark data

Citing articles: 51 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ciai20
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION, 2016
VOL. 23, NO. 02, 140156
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2016.1146124

From market fixing to market-creating: a new framework for


innovation policy
Mariana Mazzucato
Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex, Brighton, UK

ABSTRACT
Many countries are pursuing innovation-led “smart” growth, which KEYWORDS
requires long-run strategic investments and public policies that aim to Innovation policy; mission-
create and shape markets, rather than just “fixing” markets or systems. oriented policy; market
Market creation has characterized the kind of mission-oriented failures; system failures;
investments that led to putting a man on the moon and are currently directionality; smart growth;
inclusive growth
galvanizing green innovation. Mission-oriented innovation has
required public agencies to not only “de-risk” the private sector, but JEL CLASSIFICATION
also to lead the direct creation of new technological opportunities and H1; L1; L2; O1; 03
market landscapes. This paper considers four key issues that arise from
a market-creating framework for policy: (1) decision-making on the
direction of change; (2) the nature of (public and private) organizations
that can welcome the underlying uncertainty and discovery process;
(3) the evaluation of mission-oriented and market-creation policies;
and (4) the ways in which both risks and rewards can be shared so that
smart growth can also result in inclusive growth.

1. Societal challenges and opportunity-driven investments


Innovation agencies around the world are increasingly considering socioeconomic-tech-
nological challenges that can be tackled through innovation policies (EC Innovation Union;
OECD Innovation Strategy). The idea is that, through such challenges, which can relate
to such issues as climate change, cancer, or the demographic-aging crisis, innovation
policy can produce solutions for societal problems. The present paper argues that such
challenge-driven innovation policies require the traditional market failure justifications
for policy intervention, and even system failure justifications, to be complemented with a
more active market-creating framework. To this end, the paper draws on and advances an
analysis of the role of public policy in the economy that can provide a more strategic and
mission-oriented approach.
Societal challenges require technological, behavioral, and systemic changes and have
much to learn from those mission-oriented feats that led to putting humans on the moon
and to the emergence of new general-purpose technologies ranging from the Internet to
biotechnology and nanotechnology (Foray et al. 2012). It was only possible to achieve those

CONTACT Mariana Mazzucato [email protected]


© 2016 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 141

missions when the public and private sectors worked together to create new technologies
and sectors (Mowery, Nelson, and Martin 2010; Ruttan 2006). Crucially, the public side
of such partnerships was not limited to incentivizing, facilitating, or de-risking the pri-
vate sector. Rather, it required that (public) risks be taken through choosing a particular
direction of change (Mazzucato 2013a). Such directionality did not occur from the top-
down, but through a decentralized group of public agencies, what Block and Keller (2011)
refer to as a “developmental network state.” Given the immense risks involved in choosing
to develop particular sectors (such as nanotechnology), technologies (such as GPS), and
broadly defined areas (such as the green economy), the relevant public institutions had to
welcome the underlying uncertainty that such choices entail. Some options win (such as
the Internet) while others fail (such as the commercialization of the Concorde airplane).
Indeed, the success of innovative public organizations like DARPA in the US Department of
Defense, which has been responsible for the financing of Arpanet (the seed of the Internet),
has been attributed to the attention it paid to internal organizational dynamics, which
nurtured experimentation and learning (Abbate 1999; Block 2008), better enabling what
Hirshman (1967) once called “policy as process”.
Missions imply setting directions of change – that is, tilting (rather than leveling) the
playing field to favor certain types of change more than others (Mazzucato and Perez 2015).
The IT revolution was picked as was also the biotech and nanotech revolution (Block and
Keller 2011; Mazzucato 2013a). What should be the core of the policy debate is not whether
policies require picking and choosing but how to enable such picking to occur in a way
that is guided by key lessons on how to nurture a learning and adaptation process which
prevents the system from getting locked into suboptimal circumstances. Missions should
be broad enough to catalyze many different sectors (the man on moon mission required a
dozen sectors to engage) but concrete enough to translate into specific problems to solve,
so that progress toward the mission can be evaluated on a continual basis.
Thus, limiting our understanding of the role of the public sector to one that simply
“administers,” “fixes,” “regulates,” and at best “facilitates” and “de-risks” the private sector
prevents us from thinking creatively about how to allow public sector vision, risk-taking,
and investment to lead and structure the necessary transformational changes. One impact
of public choice theory has been to undermine faith in the positive power of public institu-
tions. This has provided the justification for a reduction in public sector investments in its
internal capabilities and competencies which are essential to guide such change (and has
led to a rise in outsourcing (Couch 2016) which only compounds the problem).
The view of the public sector as at best facilitating change, rather than directly creating
it, has been symptomatic of not only the market failure approach to policy intervention, but
also of the evolutionary approach that has emphasized the role of public policy in terms of
fixing system failures (Lundvall 1992). This is because the systems of innovation perspective
has focused primarily on the need to build horizontal linkages between actors. While this
contributed important insights into the framework conditions required for innovation, it
has ignored those more vertical policies required for setting the direction of change, and the
characteristics of public agencies required to set such a direction. In other words, by viewing
public sector action as solutions to problems that arise from different types of failures –
whether these be coordination failures or network failures – it has indirectly perpetuated
the view of the public sector as a passive force that can only facilitate change, rather than
lead it. Consequently, the systems perspective to policy has provided little guidance for the
142 M. MAZZUCATO

directionality that is required in a world in which different pathways of development can be


chosen even within a sector (Stirling 2014), and it provides minimal insights regarding the
nature of the actors required. Is a financialized private sector the same as a non-financial-
ized one? Are public organizations that aim to create horizontal conditions for innovation
organized in the same way as those directed at missions that require picking of specific
firms to support, particular technologies to develop, and broadly defined sectors to create?
The first key problem is that any framework that focuses on policy only in terms of fixing
problems, especially (but not only) market failures, does not embody any explicit justifi-
cation for the kind of market creation and mission-oriented directionality (and “routes”
within directions) that was required for innovations such as the Internet and nanotechnol-
ogy and is required today to address societal challenges (Mazzucato 2015). Secondly, by not
considering the state as a lead investor and market creator, such failure-based approaches
do not provide insights into the type and structure of public sector organizations that are
needed in order to provide the depth and breadth of high-risk investments. Thirdly, as long
as policy is seen only as an “intervention,” rather than a key part of the market creation and
shaping process, the type of evaluation criteria used to assess mission-oriented investments
will inevitably be problematic. Fourthly, by not describing the state as a lead risk-taker and
investor in this process, the failure-based approaches have avoided a key issue regarding
the distribution of risks and rewards between the state and the private sector.
The present paper addresses these four challenges by asking the following questions:
(1) How can public policy be understood in terms of setting the direction and route
of change; that is, shaping and creating markets rather than just fixing them
(Directionality)?
(2) How can this alternative conceptualization be translated into new dynamic indi-
cators and evaluation tools for public policies, beyond the static micro-economic
cost/benefit analysis and macro-economic appraisal of crowding in/crowding out
that stem directly from the market failure perspective (Evaluation)?
(3) How should public organizations be structured so they accommodate the risk-tak-
ing, explorative capacity and capabilities needed to envision and manage contem-
porary challenges (Organizations)?
(4) How can public investments along the innovation chain result not only in the
socialization of risks, but also of rewards, enabling smart growth to also be inclu-
sive growth (Risks and rewards)?
While the questions may seem broad, it is their potential connection that can help build
a market creation framework. Policies that aim to actively create and shape markets require
indicators that assess and measure the performance of a policy along that particular trans-
formational objective. The state’s ability and willingness to take risks, embodied in transfor-
mational changes, requires an organizational culture (and policy capacity) that welcomes
the possibility of failure and experimentation and is rewarded for successes so that failures
(which are learning opportunities) can be covered and the next round financed.
This alternative view (policy framework) of policy-making builds on the inspirational
work of Polanyi ([1944] 2001), an economic historian and sociologist who understood
markets as being deeply embedded in social institutions, and policy as not standing on the
sidelines only ‘intervening’ in the market, but central to the market creation process itself.
In his epic book The Great Transformation, Polanyi described the way in which capitalist
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 143

markets are deeply embedded in social and political institutions, rendering the usual
static state vs. market juxtaposition meaningless. As Polanyi wrote: “[t]he road to the
free market was opened and kept open by an enormous increase in continuous, centrally
organized and controlled interventionism” ([1944] 2001, 144). Polanyi’s work has been
revolutionary in terms of showing the myth of the state vs. market distinction: the most
capitalist of all markets, the national market, was forcefully pushed into existence by
the state. The market is embedded in and shaped by the state (Evans 1995). The present
paper argues, in essence, that the four above questions can help govern the dynamics of
embeddedness, so that policy choices are rendered more explicit (and hence also more
easily debated), and the results of public policies can be measured with metrics that are
adequate for a dynamic process.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the limits
of market failure theory (MFT) in describing transformational change. Section 3 considers
ways in which recent advances in heterodox economics contain the seeds of an alternative
framework to MFT. Section 4 considers the four key questions that emerge from considering
a market shaping framework. Section 5 considers the new research questions that emerge
from considering this perspective.

2. Market failure theory


MFT justifies public intervention in the economy only if it is geared toward fixing situations
in which markets fail to efficiently allocate resources (Arrow 1951). The market failure
approach suggests that governments intervene to fix markets by investing in areas char-
acterized by positive or negative externalities. For example, positive externalities arising
from public goods (which are non-rivalrous and non-excludable) will be characterized by
underinvestment by the private sector and will therefore require public investment. This is
the case for basic research, which has high spillovers that create difficulties in appropriating
private returns; consequently, basic research is characterized by too little private investment.
Negative externalities, such as those created by pollution, require public measures that cause
the private sector to internalize external costs, such as through a carbon tax.
A particular source of market failure comes from negative externalities that arise from
the production or use of goods and services such as climate change, traffic congestion, or
antibiotic resistance, for which there is no market. Many of the most significant societal
challenges are characterized as negative externalities. Such failures work at the system level;
that is, they amount to system failures. The socioeconomic system as a whole results in
costly outcomes that are undesirable from a societal point of view. For instance, climate
change can be seen as a negative externality from carbon-intensive production methods
or the burning of fossil fuels. Indeed, the Stern Review (Stern 2006) on the economics of
climate change stated that: “Climate change presents a unique challenge for economics:
it is the greatest example of market failure we have ever seen” (Stern 2006, 1). Negative
externalities are not reflected in the price system: there is no “equilibrium” price because
there is no market for negative externalities. Many economists have called for market-based
mechanisms (such as carbon pricing or carbon taxes) or neutral technology policies (such
as tax breaks) to correct for this type of market failure, both of which leave the market to
determine the direction of change.
144 M. MAZZUCATO

While MFT provides interesting insights, it is at best useful for describing a steady-
state scenario in which public policy aims to put patches on existing trajectories provided
by markets. It is less useful when policy is required to dynamically create and shape new
markets; that is, “transformation.” This means it is problematic for addressing innovation
and societal challenges because it cannot explain the kinds of transformative, catalytic,
mission-oriented public investments (Foray et al. 2012, Mazzucato and Penna 2015, Nelson
1977) that created new technologies and sectors that did not previously exist. This includes
the emergence of the Internet, the nanotechnology sector, the biotechnology sector, and the
emerging clean-tech sector (Block and Keller 2011, Sampat 2012). Such mission-oriented
investments coordinated public and private initiatives, built new networks, and drove the
entire techno-economic process, which resulted in the creation of new markets (Mazzucato
2015). This depiction is very different from assuming that the private sector is in a space
and simply needs to be incentivized to invest more or less within that space. It is the space
itself that has been created by public policy, with the private sector entering only later. The
imagination and vision emanated from the policy itself, which actively took risks rather
than just de-risking.
A key characteristic of market-creating investments is that they are not limited to
upstream basic research (the classic public good). Indeed, public investments that led to
technological revolutions (IT, biotech, nanotech) and new general-purpose technologies (such
as the Internet) were distributed along the entire innovation chain: basic research through
the National Science Foundation (NSF), applied research through DARPA and the National
Institutes of Health (NIH), and early-stage financing of companies through agencies like
Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) (Block and Keller 2011). This means that the
kinds of innovation instruments (discussed by Martin 2016, this issue) were spread across
a decentralized network of different agencies across the entire innovation chain. While
such agencies might not act together in a planned way, the history of agencies like DARPA
and NIH teaches us that they were often driven by a vision to create new landscapes (in
defense or life-sciences) rather than to only fix problems in existing landscapes. In order
to understand such mission-oriented policies, and to guide future ones, it is essential to
develop a framework that can take into account investments that direct/steer change in
particular directions, with the public sector not only de-risking, but also taking risks and
uncertainties as lead investor. A market-creating framework for policy, to complement
the market (and system) fixing role, can build on several “heterodox” economics litera-
tures that have emphasized the state’s transformational capacity. I review these alternative
literatures below.

3. Insights on market shaping/creating from alternative theories


Policies based on building systems of innovation focus on the need for nations to build a
“network of institutions in the public and private sectors whose activities and interactions
initiate, import, modify and diffuse new technologies” (Freeman 1995). The emphasis here
is not on the stock of R&D, but on the circulation of knowledge and its diffusion throughout
the economy (Lundvall 1992). Institutional change is not assessed through criteria based
on static allocative efficiency, but rather on how such change promotes technological and
structural change. This perspective is neither macro nor micro, but more meso, where indi-
vidual firms are seen as part of broader network of firms with which they cooperate and
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 145

compete. The systems of innovation approach have been crucial for highlighting deficiencies
in the market failure perspective, as it regards innovation policy (Freeman 1995; Lundvall
1992). It has emphasized the inability of MFT to tackle lock-in effects and to specific types
of institutional failures that arise from feedback processes along the entire innovation chain
(Verspagen 2006). As discussed by Brown (2016, this issue), key innovation institutions,
such as universities, will only allow the innovation system to achieve its potential if they are
lined up synergistically with other institutions in the entrepreneurial ecosystem.
However, while the systems of innovation approach have been key in identifying dynamic
system failures, it has not explicitly created an alternative policy framework. This is because
it has been associated too much with the notion of policy as fixing to the notion of policy
as fixing, rather than wholeheartedly debunking the notion of policy as an “intervention”
in the market process. In order to develop an alternative framework, the market itself must
be redefined as an outcome of the interactions between different agents, including public
policy-makers (Mazzucato 2013c).
In order to develop a market-creating view of policy, in the spirit of Karl Polanyi’s under-
standing of markets as outcomes embedded in policy processes, the paper draws on insights
from different bodies of thought that have considered the role of the state in achieving
transformation of the economic landscape. These are: (a) science and technology policy
research on mission-oriented policies; (b) development economics research on the devel-
opmental state; (c) evolutionary economics research on shifts in technological trajectories
and the emergence of techno-economic paradigms; and (d) research on the entrepreneurial
state, which looks explicitly at the risk-taking role of different actors (Mazzucato 2013a).
In Section 4, I use these insights to consider new questions for economic policy that can
help guide a market-creating framework. The fact that these four bodies of thought have
not previously been linked, and have not been clearly positioned to critique the key tenets
of MFT, has prevented them from having the impact they could have on our understanding
of how to guide, evaluate, and manage public policy.

3.1. Science and technology policy research: mission-oriented innovation policy


The history of innovation policy, studied especially through the systems of innovation
approach (Freeman 1995), provides key insights into the limits of MFT with regard to
justifying the depth and breadth of investments that have been necessary for the emer-
gence of radical technological change. Innovation policy has historically taken the shape
of measures that perform the following four functions: (1) support basic research, (2) aim
to develop and diffuse general-purpose technologies, (3) develop certain economic sectors
that are crucial for innovation, and (4) promote infrastructural development (Freeman and
Soete [1974] 1997). The justification of innovation policies has changed over time. While
military motives predominated in the 1950s and 1960s, the aim since the 1970s has been
to improve economic and competitive positions. In the 1980s, innovation policy became
increasingly justified due to market failure. Innovation policies driven by military motives
have been described as mission-oriented because they have aimed to achieve clearly defined
technical goals. There have been calls in recent years for a return to such policies to address
“grand societal challenges” (Mowery, Nelson, and Martin 2010). However, Foray, Mowery,
and Nelson (2012) contrasted missions of the past, such as putting a man on the moon,
with such contemporary missions as tackling climate change. While past missions aimed
146 M. MAZZUCATO

to develop a particular technology (with the achievement of the technological objective


signaling that the mission was accomplished), contemporary missions have addressed
broader and more persistent challenges, which require long-term commitments to the
development of technological solutions. The Maastricht Memorandum (Soete and Arundel
1993) provided a detailed analysis of the differences between old and new mission-oriented
projects, showing that:
older projects developed radically new technologies through government procurement pro-
jects that were largely isolated from the rest of the economy, though they frequently affected
the structure of related industries and could lead to new spin-off technologies that had wide-
spread effects on other sectors. In contrast, [contemporary] mission-oriented environmental
[and other] projects will need to combine procurement with many other policies in order
to have pervasive effects on the entire structure of production and consumption within an
economy. (50)
However, research in this literature has often failed to integrate empirical insights in
order to provide a fully fledged theory that contrasts with MFT. Consequently, these studies
have resulted in ad hoc theoretical understandings and policy advice on how to manage
mission-oriented initiatives, without tackling the key justifications for mission-oriented
investments in a way that contrasts the justifications that arise from MFT. In particular,
the framework has been limited to looking at agencies that focus on science, technology,
and innovation policies. Doing so ignores the relationship between types of finance and
innovation development. It also overlooks, for example, the rise of public financial insti-
tutions like state investment banks (such as KfW in Germany or the China Development
Bank) as sources of mission-oriented finance, especially as private finance has increasingly
retreated from financing the real economy (Mazzucato 2013b; Mazzucato and Penna 2014).
While mission-oriented programs are intrinsically dynamic, with feedback loops between
missions and achievements, the tools used to evaluate such public policies have remained
static, coming from the MFT toolbox. For these reasons, mission-oriented policy research
is currently confined to a small area of policy research and practice and has had minimal
impact on how economists understand the role of public policy.

3.2. Development economics: developmental network states


Work on the developmental state, a concept from a small group of development econo-
mists, has revealed the importance of the “visible hand” of the state in industrialization and
technological change (Amsden 2001; Wade 1990). More recently, this literature has also
emphasized the importance of a developmental network state; that is, a decentralized net-
work of different types of state agencies that can foster innovation and development. While
significant attention has been devoted to the role of large agencies or institutions (such as
DARPA or the NIH) in historical mission-oriented projects, it is only recently that consid-
erable focus has been placed on the broader network of structures, actors, strategies, and
agencies, such as intelligence distributed amongst actors and institutions, flat organizational
structures, flexibility, and customization (Perez 2002). Many successful cases of innovation
and technology policy strategies have been carried out by networks of decentralized public
institutions, which have focused not on creating individual “national champion” firms, but
on establishing a constellation of innovative firms (O’Riain 2004). This has been the case
in East Asia, Finland, Israel, Taiwan, and even in Silicon Valley in the United States (Block
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 147

and Keller 2011). Such successful policies have covered a wide range of measures, including
R&D support, training, support for marketing and exporting, funding programs (including
early-stage venture capital [VC]), networking and brokerage services, building of facilities
and clusters (so-called science parks), and fostering industrial ties.
From this alternative view, economic development is not the result of natural competitive
advantages, but of the endogenous creation of new opportunities that lead to the establish-
ment of competitive advantages. This process requires discovery of the cost structure of an
economy in order to identify which of the types of goods and services that already exist
in world markets can be produced in a domestic economy at low cost (Rodrik 2004). The
state plays a central coordinating role in this discovery process and often represents a lead
agent in economic development efforts. Because economic development is an endogenous
process, the state provides social capital, coordinates initiatives and public–private part-
nerships, fosters synergies, and promotes the introduction of new combinations that create
Schumpeterian rents (Reinert 2007).

3.3. Evolutionary economics: technological trajectories and techno-economic


paradigm shifts
Following the Schumpeterian tradition, evolutionary economists aim to “open the black
box of technical change” (Rosenberg 1982) with a methodology that is led by empirical
regularities and historical analysis in order to understand the process that links technical
change (innovation), economic growth, and development. Key concepts developed in evo-
lutionary economics are those of technological paradigms and technological trajectories (Dosi
1982; Nelson and Winter 1982), which reveal the limitation of market forces in providing
direction to economic development. A technological paradigm has a threefold definition:
it is an outlook of the relevant productive problems confronted by firms (as producers of
technologies or innovators); it represents a set of procedures (routines) of how these prob-
lems shall be approached; and it defines the relevant problems and associated knowledge
necessary for their solution (Dosi 1982, 148).
The evolutionary focus on the co-evolution of those processes creating variety between
economic agents and the competitive selection process that winnows in on that variety,
means that an evolutionary perspective on policy must consider adaptation (Flanagan and
Uyarra 2016, this issue; Witt 2003). Policies should not be viewed as general a priori answers,
but as being about learning and emergence. Which policy is best in which environment
will emerge from experimentation and trial and error. A technological trajectory, in turn,
represents the direction of learning, experimentation, and progress within a technological
paradigm. Therefore, technology development is a problem-solving activity, and a tech-
nological paradigm “embodies strong prescriptions on the directions of technical change”
(Dosi 1982, 152). This is why market signals are limited in terms of providing direction
to techno-economic development; they only work within the parameters of the paradigm,
which means they influence the rate of change more than the direction. When two or more
technological paradigms compete, markets may influence which one is selected (the one that
minimizes costs). Once established, however, paradigms have a powerful “exclusion effect,”
whereby some technological possibilities are discarded because they are incompatible with
the prevailing paradigm and are therefore “invisible” to agents. Thus, a techno-economic
system of innovation may be locked into a self-reinforcing, path-dependent trajectory (Dosi
148 M. MAZZUCATO

and Nelson 1994). This becomes a problem if the trajectory being followed (or the paradigm
itself) is inferior or suboptimal to what could be achieved with technologies that transgress
the paradigm (or with a different paradigm).
Perez (2002) expanded the notion of technological paradigm to techno-economic para-
digm in order to account for the non-technological forces (economic and social institutions)
that characterize certain periods of capitalist history and affect both the economic and social
systems. Her theory of techno-economic paradigm shifts is a historical perspective on the
long waves of development that accompany technological revolutions.
A techno-economic paradigm is, then, a best-practice model made up of a set of all-pervasive
generic technological and organizational principles, which represent the most effective way of
applying a particular technological revolution and of using it for modernizing and rejuvenating
the whole of the economy. (Perez 2002, 15)
When a new technological revolution emerges, the socioeconomic system remains stuck
within the bounds of the previous paradigm. This renders market forces incapable of direct-
ing the system toward the new paradigm and stifles the modernizing and rejuvenating
potential of the new revolution. In other words, there are mismatches between elements of
the social and techno-economic systems (for example, social expectations, R&D routines,
tax regimes, labor regulations). In order to overcome these mismatches, it is necessary to
build new institutions that favor the diffusion of the new paradigm. In all previous techno-
logical revolutions, governments have led the process of institution-building that allowed
new techno-economic paradigms to replace the old ones. Perez (2002) specifically pointed
to the role that public policy plays in allowing the full deployment of technological revolu-
tions, such as the effect of suburbanization on the ability of the mass production revolution
to diffuse throughout the economy.
This stream of research on technological and techno-economic paradigms highlights the
importance of cognition when establishing the direction of technological change. Paradigms
are powerful enabling and constraining institutions that favor certain directions of tech-
no-economic development and obstruct others. In order to redirect techno-economic devel-
opment on a new, qualitatively different route, a paradigm shift is required that will avoid the
constant renewal of prevailing trajectories that occurs if market forces provide directionality
to the system. From this perspective, the state has a crucial role to play in terms of creating
a new vision that will coordinate cognitive efforts of different (public and private) agents
and direct their action to areas beyond the existing paradigm. Green innovation can be
understood as a redirection of the full deployment of the IT revolution (Mazzucato and Perez
2015). In order to effectively provide the direction of change, a vision must be created and
shared. Stirling (2008) correctly focused on the role of bottom-up participatory processes
to ensure directionality is taken seriously and shared amongst actors.

3.4. The entrepreneurial state: the state as lead risk-taker and investor in the
economy
Alternative approaches to innovation policy, such as those described above, have questioned
particular aspects of the economic dynamics embodied in neoclassical theory. However,
they have not questioned the underlying assumption of business being the only risk-taker.
The entrepreneurial state agenda has sought to challenge the notion of the entrepreneur
being embodied in private business, and policy-making being an activity outside of the
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 149

entrepreneurial process (Mazzucato 2013a). This perspective builds on studies in industry


dynamics that have documented a weak relationship between entry of new firms into indus-
tries and the current levels of profits in those industries (Vivarelli 2013). Firm entry appears
to be driven by expectations about future growth opportunities, even when such expectations
are overly optimistic (Dosi and Lovallo 1998). Historically, such technological and market
opportunities have been actively shaped by government investment – what Mazzucato
(2013a) refers to as “the entrepreneurial state”; that is, a willingness to invest in, and some-
times imagine from the beginning, new high-risk areas before the private sector does.
Business has tended to enter new sectors only after the high risk and uncertainty has been
absorbed by the public sector, especially in areas of high capital intensity. This has been the
case with the IT revolution (Block and Keller 2011), the biotechnology industry (Lazonick
and Tulum 2011), nanotechnology (Motoyama, Appelbaum, and Parker 2011), and for the
emerging clean-tech sector (Mazzucato and Penna 2014). Indeed, Keller and Block (2013)
have shown that private VC funds have focused on financing firms mid-stage, which had
previously received early-stage financing by public programs, like the SBIR program. The
literature has ignored such private piggybacking on public risk-taking, at best discussing it
in terms of “crowding in.” What crowding in ignores, however, is the direct risk-taking that
such (public) activity entails, and hence the occasional failures that will inevitably result.
In the book The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths, Mazzucato
(2013a) describes the risk-taking role the state has played in the few countries that have
achieved innovation-led growth. Ignoring the high risk and uncertainty that the state has
absorbed has caused the fruits of innovation-led growth to be privatized, even though the
underlying risk was socialized. It is usually assumed that the returns to the state will occur indi-
rectly through the spillovers that are generated and/or through tax revenue. However, this type
of return is based on the assumption that the state intervention is limited to upstream areas
like basic research (with high spillovers). However, the traditional assumptions breakdown
when the intervention occurs throughout the entire innovation chain, including for applied
research for technologies that get appropriated by specific firms, and on early-stage high-risk
company financing. It also breaks down when spillovers are blocked through upstream pat-
enting, an increasing trend (Mazzoleni and Nelson, 1998). And also when taxes are avoided
and evaded by companies which have benefited by different types of public support.
Thus, the entrepreneurial state framework implies considering both indirect and direct
“reward” mechanisms for the public policies. Such mechanisms can make it easier for public
organizations to treat their investments as portfolios, able to make some return on the upside
to cover the downside as well as the next round of investments. More evidence is needed
from around the world regarding the challenges and opportunities related to different types
of return-generating mechanisms for public investments, such as those in Israel (through
Yozma), the US (through In-Q-tel), and Finland (through SITRA). This will help generate
insights into the role of the state as a spender, facilitator, and regulator, but also as an inves-
tor and venture capitalist (Mazzucato 2013a; Rodrik 2015). How to do this, while retaining
a mission-oriented perspective (not limited by cost–benefit analysis), is a key challenge.

4. Beyond market failure: routes, organization, assessment, and rewards


New economic thinking is required in order to build a policy framework that can be oriented
towards market creating, rather than just market fixing, and can be focused on transforming
150 M. MAZZUCATO

the economic landscape rather than just facilitating it. This section brings together key
concepts from the four heterodox frameworks reviewed above, drawing especially on the
empirical research conducted within these perspectives, in order to provide a new theoretical
conceptualization for guiding state action to tackle transformational change. The section
considers four new policy questions, which can help build a market-creating policy agenda
(Mazzucato 2015).

4.1. Directionality: understanding the role of policy as setting the direction of


change
Policies that aim to correct markets assume that once the sources of the failure have been
addressed, market forces will efficiently direct the economy to a path of growth and devel-
opment. However, markets are “blind” (Dosi 1982) and the direction of change provided by
markets often represents suboptimal outcomes from a societal point of view. This is why, in
addressing societal challenges, states have led the process and provided the direction towards
new techno-economic paradigms that did not emerge spontaneously out of market forces.
Governments made direct investments in the technologies that enabled the mass production
and IT revolutions to emerge, and formulated bold policies that allowed these phenomena
to be fully deployed throughout the economy (Block and Keller 2011; Ruttan 2006). This
fact seems to point to different analytical problems facing policy-makers, namely choosing
whether the correct course of action is to direct or stand back; understanding how par-
ticular directions and routes can be picked; and determining how to mobilize and manage
activities that can lead to the achievement of dynamic social and technological challenges.
The problem is not whether to pick a direction, but how to learn from the successful
picking of the past, and to enable the directions picked to be broad enough to allow bot-
tom-up exploration, discovery, and learning. This is sometimes referred to as “smart spe-
cialization” (Foray, David, and Hall 2009) and is explicitly a results- and outcome-oriented
agenda, not an input- or outputs-oriented one (Rodrik 2004). However, the fact that it has
hitherto been based on a market failure framework means that smart specialization is, at
best, considered a “discovery” process with which stakeholders and policy-designers can
jointly identify bottlenecks, market failures, and missing links. Smart specialization has
not addressed the way in which innovation-led growth in places like Silicon Valley actually
happened. Doing so requires not only the identification of missing links, but the formation
of concrete strategies towards producing market landscapes that simply did not exist in
the past. It also requires that the playing field be tilted in the direction pursued, rather than
leveled (Mazzucato and Perez 2015).

4.2. Organization: transforming public organizations into ones that welcome


learning, experimentation, and self-discovery
If brought to its extreme, as advocated by critics from public choice theory, MFT calls for
the state to intervene as little as possible in the economy, in a way that minimizes the risk
of government failure, from crowding out to cronyism and corruption. This view requires
a structure that insulates the public sector from the private sector (to avoid issues such as
agency capture) and has resulted in a trend of outsourcing that often rids government of the
knowledge capacities and capabilities (in relation to IT, for example) that are necessary for
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 151

managing change (Kakabadse and Kakabadse 2002). More studies are needed to examine
the influence of outsourcing on the ability of public institutions to attract top-level talent
with the relevant knowledge and skills to manage transformative mission-oriented policies.
Without such talent and expertise, it is nearly impossible for the state to fulfill its role of
coordinating and providing direction to private actors when formulating and implementing
policies that address societal challenges. In order to promote transformation of the economy,
by shaping and creating technologies, sectors, and markets, the state must organize itself
so that it has the intelligence (policy capacity) to think big and formulate bold policies.
If the state is essential to the process of transformative technological and socioeconomic
change, it is also essential to understand the appropriate structure of public organizations.
Innovation is subject to extreme uncertainty, which creates the need for both patience
(“patient long-term capital”, Mazzucato 2013b) and the ability to experiment and explore
the underlying landscape (Rodrik 2004). Therefore, a crucial element in organizing the
state for its market-creating role is building its absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal
1990), a concept that has hitherto been restricted to private organizations. This absorptive
capacity will enable public agencies to learn in a process of investment, discovery, and
experimentation, and see policy as process (Hirschman 1967).
A key concern should be to establish skills/resources, capabilities, and structures that
can increase the chances that a public organization will be effective, both at learning and at
establishing symbiotic partnerships with the private sector, and ultimately succeed in imple-
menting mission-oriented and transformative policies. Public and private organizations
must re-rethink their roles when working together. Public–private partnerships have often
limited the public part in de-risking the private part. This ignores the capabilities and chal-
lenges involved in public sector risk-taking. De-risking assumes a conservative strategy that
minimizes the risks of picking losing projects, but does not necessarily maximize the prob-
ability of picking winners, which requires the adoption of a portfolio approach for public
investments (Rodrik 2013). In such an approach, the success of a few projects can cover
the losses from many projects, and the public organization in question also learns from its
loss-making investments (Mazzucato 2013a). Here, the matching between failures and fixes
is less important than having an institutional structure that ensures that winning policies
provide enough rewards to cover the losses, and that losses are used as lessons to improve
and renew future policies. Research on the developmental state (Block and Keller 2011) sug-
gests that these goals are best achieved not through heavy top-down policies, but through
a decentralized structure in which the organization(s) involved remain nimble, innovative,
and dynamic from within (Breznitz and Ornston 2013). This strand of thinking can benefit
from looking at the ways in which public–private partnerships were created when seeking
the joint creation of new products and services, including vaccines (Chataway et al. 2007).

4.3. Evaluation: transforming static metrics into dynamic ones


The market failure framework has developed concrete indicators and methods to evaluate
government investments, which stem directly from the framework itself, usually through
a cost–benefit analysis that estimates whether the benefits of public intervention compen-
sate for the costs associated with the market failure and with the implementation of the
policy (including governmental failures). The problem is that there is a mismatch between
152 M. MAZZUCATO

the intrinsically dynamic character of economic development and the static tools used to
evaluate the role of the public policy in the process.
Failure to allow for the possibility that government can transform and create new land-
scapes that did not previously exist will affect the ability to measure such impact. This is
evident in innovation and also for public services (Crouch 2016). This situation then leads
to accusations of government crowding out business investment, which implies that the
areas that government moves into could have been areas for business investment. Such
claims are best defended through a crowding in argument, which relies on showing how
government investments create a larger national output pie (hence higher savings for private
investment to dip into). Indeed, as shown by Engel, Rothgang, and Eckl (2016, this issue),
public investments in R&D often crowd in further R&D investments by business.
However, a crowding in argument cannot provide a full explanation. It does not account
for the fact that businesses are frequently risk-averse and unwilling or unable to transform
existing landscapes or create new ones. Without indicators for such transformative action,
the static toolbox affects the government’s ability to determine whether it is simply operating
in existing spaces or making new things happen that would not have happened anyway (its
“additionality”). This often leads to investments that are overly narrow or directed within the
confines of the boundaries set by the business practices of the prevailing techno-economic
paradigm (Abraham 2010).
Therefore, it is crucial to develop a new toolbox and indicators for evaluating and measur-
ing the degree to which state investments open up and transform sectoral and technological
landscapes, rather than tinkering with existing ones. The indicators must take into account
the underlying risk and uncertainty absorbed in transforming such landscapes.

4.4. Risks and rewards: building symbiotic private–public partnerships


MFT says little about cases in which the state is the lead investor and risk taker in capitalist
economies. Having a vision about the direction in which to drive an economy requires direct
and indirect investment in particular areas, not just creating the (framework) conditions for
change. Crucial choices must be made, the fruits of which will create some winners, but also
many losers. For example, the US Department of Energy recently provided guaranteed loans
to two green-tech companies: Solyndra ($500 million) and Tesla Motors ($465 million).
While the latter is often glorified as a success story, the former failed miserably and became
the latest example in the media of government being inefficient and unable to pick winners
(Wood 2012). However, any venture capitalist will admit that for every winning investment
(such as Tesla) there are many losses (such as Solyndra). In making its downstream invest-
ments, therefore, governments can learn from portfolio strategies of venture capitalists,
structuring investments across a risk space so that lower risk investments can help to cover
the higher risk ones. In other words, if the public sector is expected to compensate for the
lack of private VC money going to early-stage innovation, it should at least be able to benefit
from the wins, as private VC does. Otherwise, the funding for such investments cannot
be secured. As argued in Mazzucato and Wray (2015), even if money could be secured for
public investments endogenously (through money creation), it is desirable to allow the state
to reap some of the rewards from its investments for a number of other reasons. Matching
this type of spending with the corresponding return would provide a measure of efficiency,
holding policy-makers accountable; government net spending has limits dictated by the real
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 153

resource capacity of the economy; and voters will be more willing to accept the (inevitable)
failures if they see that those are compensated by important successes.
The public sector can use a number of return-generating mechanisms for its investments,
including retaining equity or royalties, retaining a golden share of the IPR, using income-con-
tingent loans, or capping the prices (which the tax payer pays) of those products that ema-
nate, as drugs do, from public funds (Angell, 2005; Mazzucato 2013a). Before exploring the
details of each mechanism, however, it is crucial for the policy framework to even allow the
question to be asked. In a market-shaping framework, does government have the right to
retain equity more than in a market failure framework? Are taxes currently bringing back
enough return to government budgets to fund high-risk investments that will probably fail?

5. Conclusion
This paper has considered the limitations of the market failure framework that continues to
guide innovation policy. It has argued that putting innovation at the center of growth policy
requires an emphasis on shaping and creating markets, rather than just fixing them and
that an alternative framework must also go beyond fixing system failures. To guide a mar-
ket-creating view, the paper has considered insights from alternative (heterodox) literatures
on the role of the state into producing structural change and transformation. Four critical
issues must be considered when building such a framework: (1) the direction of change
promoted by policy; (2) the nature of (public and private) organizations that can welcome
the underlying uncertainty and discovery process; (3) the evaluation of mission-oriented
and market-creation policies; and (4) the ways in which both risks and rewards can be shared
so that smart growth can also result in inclusive growth.
Considering the need for government policy to transform, be catalytic, and create and
shape markets rather just fix them helps reframe the key questions of economic policy from
static ones that deal with crowding out and picking winners to more dynamic ones that help
form the types of public–private interactions that can create new innovation and industrial
landscapes. The point is not to prescribe specific technologies, but to provide directions of
change around which bottom-up solutions can then experiment. As Stirling (2014, 2) put it:
The more demanding the innovation challenges like poverty, ill health or environmental dam-
age, the greater becomes the importance of effective policy. This is not a question of “picking
winners” – an uncertainty-shrouded dilemma which is anyhow equally shared between public,
private and third sectors. Instead, it is about engaging widely across society, in order to build
the most fruitful conditions for deciding what ‘winning’ even means.
While identifying key societal challenges is straightforward – climate change, aging,
resource security, housing, urbanization, etc. – translating challenges into concrete mis-
sions will require the involvement of an array of stakeholders concerned with sectors and
socio-technical fields affected by the challenge itself. Therefore, defining the direction of
investments should be based on sound diagnosis of each challenge by the state together
with other stakeholders.

Acknowledgements
Comments from Caetano Penna and an anonymous referee from the SPRU working paper series are
greatly appreciated. All errors remain the author’s.
154 M. MAZZUCATO

Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Funding
The author acknowledges funding from a research grant funded by European Community’s H2020-
Euro-Society-2014 call on 'Overcoming the crisis: new ideas, strategies and governance structures
for Europe’ ” (ISIG grant no. 649186).

References
Abbate, J. 1999. Inventing the Internet. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Abraham, J. 2010. “Pharmaceuticalization of Society in Context: Theoretical, Empirical and Health
Dimensions.” Sociology 44 (4): 603–622.
Amsden, A. H. 2001. The Rise of “the Rest”. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Arrow, K. 1951. An Extension of the Basic Theorems of Classical Welfare Economics. Paper presented
at the Second Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Berkeley.
Block, F. L. 2008. “Swimming against the Current: The Rise of a Hidden Developmental State in the
United States”. Politics and Society 36 (2, June): 169–206.
Block, F. L., and M. R. Keller. 2011. State of Innovation: The U.S. Government’s Role in Technology
Development. Boulder, CO: Paradigm.
Breznitz, D., and D. Ornston. 2013. “The Revolutionary Power of Peripheral Agencies: Explaining
Radical Policy Innovation in Finland and Israel.” Comparative Political Studies 46 (10): 1219–1245.
Brown, R. 2016. “Mission Impossible? The Role of Universities in Peripheral Regional Innovative
Systems” by Ross Brown. Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Buchanan, J. M. 2003. “Public Choice: The Origins and Development of a Research Program.”
Champions of Freedom 31: 13–32.
Chataway, J., S. Brusoni, E. Cacciatori, R. Hanlin, and L. Orsenigo. 2007. “The International AIDS
Vaccine Initiative (IAVI) in a Changing Landscape of Vaccine Development: A Public/Private
Partnership as Knowledge Broker and Integrator.” The European Journal of Development Research
19 (1): 100–117.
Cohen, W. M., and D. A. Levinthal. 1990. “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and
Innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1): 128–152.
Crouch, Co. 2016. Rethinking Capitalism, edited by M. Jacobs and M. Mazzucato. London: Wiley
(forthcoming).
Dosi, G. 1982. “Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories.” Research Policy 11 (3):
147–162.
Dosi, G., and D. Lovallo. 1998. “Rational Entrepreneurs or Optimistic Martyrs? Some Considerations
on Technological Regimes, Corporate Entries, and the Evolutionary Role of Decision Biases.” In
Foresights and Oversights in Technological Change, edited by R. Garud, P. Nayyar, and Z. Shapiro,
41–68. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dosi, G., and R. R. Nelson. 1994. “An Introduction to Evolutionary Theories in Economics.” Journal
of Evolutionary Economics 4 (3): 153–172.
Engel, D., M. Rothgang, and V. Eckl. 2016. “The design of innovation policy and its effects on private
R&D.” Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Evans, P. B. 1995. Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation (Vol. 25). Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Flanagan, K., and E. Uyarra. 2016. “Innovation policy analysis, policy complexity and the scope for
successful policy action in an evolutionary world.” Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Foray, D., P. A. David, and B. Hall. 2009. “Smart Specialization: The Concept.” In Knowledge for Growth.
Prospects for Science, Technology and Innovation. Selected papers from Research Commissioner
Janez Potočnik’s Expert Group, 20.
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 155

Foray, D., D. Mowery, and R. R. Nelson. 2012. “Public R&D and Social Challenges: What Lessons
from Mission R&D Programs?” Research Policy 41 (10): 1697–1702.
Freeman, C. 1995. “The ‘National System of Innovation’ in Historical Perspective.” Cambridge Journal
of Economics 19 (1): 5–24.
Freeman, C., and L. Soete. [1974] 1997. The Economics of Industrial Innovation. 3rd ed. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Hirschman, A. O. 1967. Development Projects Observed. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kakabadse, A., and N. Kakabadse. 2002. “Trends in Outsourcing.” European Management Journal
20 (2): 189–198.
Keller, M. R., and F. Block. 2013. “Explaining the Transformation in the US Innovation System: The
Impact of a Small Government Program.” Socio-Economic Review 11 (4): 629–656.
Lazonick, W., and O. Tulum. 2011. “US Biopharmaceutical Finance and the Sustainability of the
Biotech Business Model.” Research Policy 40 (9): 1170–1187.
Lundvall, B. A. 1992. National Innovation System: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive
Learning. London: Pinter.
Martin, B. R. 2016. “R&D Policy Instruments – a Critical Review of What We Do and Don’t Know.”
Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Mazzoleni, R., and R. R. Nelson. 1998. “The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: A
Contribution to the Current Debate.” Research Policy 27 (3): 273–284.
Mazzucato, M. 2013a. The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking the Public Vs. Private Myth in Risk and
Innovation. London: Anthem Press.
Mazzucato, M. 2013b. “Financing Innovation: Creative Destruction Vs. Destructive Creation.”
Industrial and Corporate Change 22 (4): 851–867.
Mazzucato, M. 2013c. “Debunking the Market Mechanism: Organisations, Innovation and Inequality
– A Response to John Kay.” Political Quarterly 84 (4): 444–447.
Mazzucato, M. 2015. “Innovation Systems: From Fixing Market Failures to Creating Markets.”
Intereconomics 50 (3): 120–155.
Mazzucato, M., and C. C. R. Penna. 2014. “Beyond Market Failures: State Investment Banks and the
‘Mission-Oriented’ Finance for Innovation.” SPRU Working Paper Series 21.
Mazzucato, M., and C. C. R. Penna, eds. 2015. Mission-Oriented Finance for Innovation: New Ideas
for Investment-Led Growth. London: Pickering & Chatto ; Rowman & Littlefield.
Mazzucato, M., and C. Perez. 2015. “Innovation as Growth Policy,” in The Triple Challenge: Europe in
a New Age, edited by J. Fagerberg, S. Laestadius, and B. Martin. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mazzucato, M., and R. Wray. 2015. “Financing the Capital Development of the Economy: A Keynes–
Schumpeter–Minsky Synthesis.” Levy Institute Working Paper No. 837.
Motoyama, Y., R. Appelbaum, and R. Parker. 2011. “The National Nanotechnology Initiative: Federal
Support for Science and Technology, or Hidden Industrial Policy?” Technology in Society 33 (1–2):
109–118.
Mowery, D. C. 2010. “Military R&D and Innovation.” In Handbook of the Economics of Innovation
(Vol. 2), edited by B. H. Hall, and N. Rosenberg, 1219–1256. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Mowery, D. C., R. R. Nelson, and B. R. Martin. 2010. “Technology Policy and Global Warming: Why
New Policy Models Are Needed (or Why Putting New Wine in Old Bottles Won’t Work).” Research
Policy 39 (8): 1011–1023.
Nelson, R. R. (1977). The moon and the ghetto. New York: Norton.
Nelson, R. R., and S. G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA:
Belknap Press.
O’Riain, S. 2004. The Politics of High Tech Growth. Boston, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Perez, C. 2002. Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. Cheltenham: Edgar Elgar.
Polanyi, K. [1944] 2001. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.
(2nd Beacon Paperback ed.). Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Reinert, E. S. 2007. How Rich Countries Got Rich and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor. London:
Constable.
Rodrik, D. 2004. “Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century.” John F. Kennedy School of
Government Working Paper Series rwp04–047.
156 M. MAZZUCATO

Rodrik, D. 2013. “Green Industrial Policy.” Princeton University Working Paper.


Rodrik, D. 2014. “From Welfare State to Innovation State,” Project Syndicate, Accessed March 3, 2015.
http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/labor-saving-technology-by-dani-rodrik-2015-01
Rodrik, D. 2015. “From the Welfare State to the Innovation State,” Project Syndicate. http://www.
project-syndicate.org/commentary/labor-saving-technology-by-dani-rodrik-2015-01?barrier=true
Rosenberg, N. 1982. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics. Boston, MA: Cambridge
University Press.
Ruttan, V. W. 2006. Is War Necessary for Economic Growth? Department of Applied Economics:
University of Minnesota.
Sampat, B. N. 2012. “Mission-Oriented Biomedical Research at the NIH.” Research Policy 41 (10):
1729–1741.
Soete, L., and A. Arundel. 1993. An Integrated Approach to European Innovation and Technology
Diffusion Policy: A Maastricht Memorandum. Luxembourg: Commission of the European
Communities, SPRINT Programme.
Stern, N. H. 2006. The Economics of Climate Change (Stern Review). HM Treasury.
Stirling, A. 2008. “‘Opening Up’ and ‘Closing Down’ Power, Participation, and Pluralism in the Social
Appraisal of Technology.” Science, Technology & Human Values 33 (2): 262–294.
Stirling, A. 2014. Making Choices in the Face of Uncertainty. Themed Annual Report of the Government
Chief Scientific Adviser, Chapter 2 (June). Draft mimeo.
Verspagen, B. 2006. “Innovation and Economic Growth.” In The Oxford Handbook of Innovation,
edited by J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery, and R. R. Nelson, 487–513. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Vivarelli, M. 2013. “Is Entrepreneurship Necessarily Good? Microeconomic Evidence from Developed
and Developing Countries.” Industrial and Corporate Change 22 (6): 1453–1495.
Wade, R. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Industrialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Witt, U. 2003. “Economic Policy Making in Evolutionary Perspective.” Journal of Evolutionary
Economics 13 (2): 77–94.
Wood, R. 2012. Fallen Solyndra Won Bankruptcy Battle but Faces Tax War. Forbes, 11 June. Accessed
June 29, 2014. http://www.forbes.com/sites/robertwood/2012/11/06/fallen-solyndra-won-
bankruptcy-battle-but-faces-tax-war/