Mazzucato 16 - From Market Fixing To Market Creating A New Framework For Innovation Policy
Mazzucato 16 - From Market Fixing To Market Creating A New Framework For Innovation Policy
Mazzucato 16 - From Market Fixing To Market Creating A New Framework For Innovation Policy
Mariana Mazzucato
To cite this article: Mariana Mazzucato (2016) From market fixing to market-creating:
a new framework for innovation policy, Industry and Innovation, 23:2, 140-156, DOI:
10.1080/13662716.2016.1146124
ABSTRACT
Many countries are pursuing innovation-led “smart” growth, which KEYWORDS
requires long-run strategic investments and public policies that aim to Innovation policy; mission-
create and shape markets, rather than just “fixing” markets or systems. oriented policy; market
Market creation has characterized the kind of mission-oriented failures; system failures;
investments that led to putting a man on the moon and are currently directionality; smart growth;
inclusive growth
galvanizing green innovation. Mission-oriented innovation has
required public agencies to not only “de-risk” the private sector, but JEL CLASSIFICATION
also to lead the direct creation of new technological opportunities and H1; L1; L2; O1; 03
market landscapes. This paper considers four key issues that arise from
a market-creating framework for policy: (1) decision-making on the
direction of change; (2) the nature of (public and private) organizations
that can welcome the underlying uncertainty and discovery process;
(3) the evaluation of mission-oriented and market-creation policies;
and (4) the ways in which both risks and rewards can be shared so that
smart growth can also result in inclusive growth.
missions when the public and private sectors worked together to create new technologies
and sectors (Mowery, Nelson, and Martin 2010; Ruttan 2006). Crucially, the public side
of such partnerships was not limited to incentivizing, facilitating, or de-risking the pri-
vate sector. Rather, it required that (public) risks be taken through choosing a particular
direction of change (Mazzucato 2013a). Such directionality did not occur from the top-
down, but through a decentralized group of public agencies, what Block and Keller (2011)
refer to as a “developmental network state.” Given the immense risks involved in choosing
to develop particular sectors (such as nanotechnology), technologies (such as GPS), and
broadly defined areas (such as the green economy), the relevant public institutions had to
welcome the underlying uncertainty that such choices entail. Some options win (such as
the Internet) while others fail (such as the commercialization of the Concorde airplane).
Indeed, the success of innovative public organizations like DARPA in the US Department of
Defense, which has been responsible for the financing of Arpanet (the seed of the Internet),
has been attributed to the attention it paid to internal organizational dynamics, which
nurtured experimentation and learning (Abbate 1999; Block 2008), better enabling what
Hirshman (1967) once called “policy as process”.
Missions imply setting directions of change – that is, tilting (rather than leveling) the
playing field to favor certain types of change more than others (Mazzucato and Perez 2015).
The IT revolution was picked as was also the biotech and nanotech revolution (Block and
Keller 2011; Mazzucato 2013a). What should be the core of the policy debate is not whether
policies require picking and choosing but how to enable such picking to occur in a way
that is guided by key lessons on how to nurture a learning and adaptation process which
prevents the system from getting locked into suboptimal circumstances. Missions should
be broad enough to catalyze many different sectors (the man on moon mission required a
dozen sectors to engage) but concrete enough to translate into specific problems to solve,
so that progress toward the mission can be evaluated on a continual basis.
Thus, limiting our understanding of the role of the public sector to one that simply
“administers,” “fixes,” “regulates,” and at best “facilitates” and “de-risks” the private sector
prevents us from thinking creatively about how to allow public sector vision, risk-taking,
and investment to lead and structure the necessary transformational changes. One impact
of public choice theory has been to undermine faith in the positive power of public institu-
tions. This has provided the justification for a reduction in public sector investments in its
internal capabilities and competencies which are essential to guide such change (and has
led to a rise in outsourcing (Couch 2016) which only compounds the problem).
The view of the public sector as at best facilitating change, rather than directly creating
it, has been symptomatic of not only the market failure approach to policy intervention, but
also of the evolutionary approach that has emphasized the role of public policy in terms of
fixing system failures (Lundvall 1992). This is because the systems of innovation perspective
has focused primarily on the need to build horizontal linkages between actors. While this
contributed important insights into the framework conditions required for innovation, it
has ignored those more vertical policies required for setting the direction of change, and the
characteristics of public agencies required to set such a direction. In other words, by viewing
public sector action as solutions to problems that arise from different types of failures –
whether these be coordination failures or network failures – it has indirectly perpetuated
the view of the public sector as a passive force that can only facilitate change, rather than
lead it. Consequently, the systems perspective to policy has provided little guidance for the
142 M. MAZZUCATO
markets are deeply embedded in social and political institutions, rendering the usual
static state vs. market juxtaposition meaningless. As Polanyi wrote: “[t]he road to the
free market was opened and kept open by an enormous increase in continuous, centrally
organized and controlled interventionism” ([1944] 2001, 144). Polanyi’s work has been
revolutionary in terms of showing the myth of the state vs. market distinction: the most
capitalist of all markets, the national market, was forcefully pushed into existence by
the state. The market is embedded in and shaped by the state (Evans 1995). The present
paper argues, in essence, that the four above questions can help govern the dynamics of
embeddedness, so that policy choices are rendered more explicit (and hence also more
easily debated), and the results of public policies can be measured with metrics that are
adequate for a dynamic process.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the limits
of market failure theory (MFT) in describing transformational change. Section 3 considers
ways in which recent advances in heterodox economics contain the seeds of an alternative
framework to MFT. Section 4 considers the four key questions that emerge from considering
a market shaping framework. Section 5 considers the new research questions that emerge
from considering this perspective.
While MFT provides interesting insights, it is at best useful for describing a steady-
state scenario in which public policy aims to put patches on existing trajectories provided
by markets. It is less useful when policy is required to dynamically create and shape new
markets; that is, “transformation.” This means it is problematic for addressing innovation
and societal challenges because it cannot explain the kinds of transformative, catalytic,
mission-oriented public investments (Foray et al. 2012, Mazzucato and Penna 2015, Nelson
1977) that created new technologies and sectors that did not previously exist. This includes
the emergence of the Internet, the nanotechnology sector, the biotechnology sector, and the
emerging clean-tech sector (Block and Keller 2011, Sampat 2012). Such mission-oriented
investments coordinated public and private initiatives, built new networks, and drove the
entire techno-economic process, which resulted in the creation of new markets (Mazzucato
2015). This depiction is very different from assuming that the private sector is in a space
and simply needs to be incentivized to invest more or less within that space. It is the space
itself that has been created by public policy, with the private sector entering only later. The
imagination and vision emanated from the policy itself, which actively took risks rather
than just de-risking.
A key characteristic of market-creating investments is that they are not limited to
upstream basic research (the classic public good). Indeed, public investments that led to
technological revolutions (IT, biotech, nanotech) and new general-purpose technologies (such
as the Internet) were distributed along the entire innovation chain: basic research through
the National Science Foundation (NSF), applied research through DARPA and the National
Institutes of Health (NIH), and early-stage financing of companies through agencies like
Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) (Block and Keller 2011). This means that the
kinds of innovation instruments (discussed by Martin 2016, this issue) were spread across
a decentralized network of different agencies across the entire innovation chain. While
such agencies might not act together in a planned way, the history of agencies like DARPA
and NIH teaches us that they were often driven by a vision to create new landscapes (in
defense or life-sciences) rather than to only fix problems in existing landscapes. In order
to understand such mission-oriented policies, and to guide future ones, it is essential to
develop a framework that can take into account investments that direct/steer change in
particular directions, with the public sector not only de-risking, but also taking risks and
uncertainties as lead investor. A market-creating framework for policy, to complement
the market (and system) fixing role, can build on several “heterodox” economics litera-
tures that have emphasized the state’s transformational capacity. I review these alternative
literatures below.
compete. The systems of innovation approach have been crucial for highlighting deficiencies
in the market failure perspective, as it regards innovation policy (Freeman 1995; Lundvall
1992). It has emphasized the inability of MFT to tackle lock-in effects and to specific types
of institutional failures that arise from feedback processes along the entire innovation chain
(Verspagen 2006). As discussed by Brown (2016, this issue), key innovation institutions,
such as universities, will only allow the innovation system to achieve its potential if they are
lined up synergistically with other institutions in the entrepreneurial ecosystem.
However, while the systems of innovation approach have been key in identifying dynamic
system failures, it has not explicitly created an alternative policy framework. This is because
it has been associated too much with the notion of policy as fixing to the notion of policy
as fixing, rather than wholeheartedly debunking the notion of policy as an “intervention”
in the market process. In order to develop an alternative framework, the market itself must
be redefined as an outcome of the interactions between different agents, including public
policy-makers (Mazzucato 2013c).
In order to develop a market-creating view of policy, in the spirit of Karl Polanyi’s under-
standing of markets as outcomes embedded in policy processes, the paper draws on insights
from different bodies of thought that have considered the role of the state in achieving
transformation of the economic landscape. These are: (a) science and technology policy
research on mission-oriented policies; (b) development economics research on the devel-
opmental state; (c) evolutionary economics research on shifts in technological trajectories
and the emergence of techno-economic paradigms; and (d) research on the entrepreneurial
state, which looks explicitly at the risk-taking role of different actors (Mazzucato 2013a).
In Section 4, I use these insights to consider new questions for economic policy that can
help guide a market-creating framework. The fact that these four bodies of thought have
not previously been linked, and have not been clearly positioned to critique the key tenets
of MFT, has prevented them from having the impact they could have on our understanding
of how to guide, evaluate, and manage public policy.
and Keller 2011). Such successful policies have covered a wide range of measures, including
R&D support, training, support for marketing and exporting, funding programs (including
early-stage venture capital [VC]), networking and brokerage services, building of facilities
and clusters (so-called science parks), and fostering industrial ties.
From this alternative view, economic development is not the result of natural competitive
advantages, but of the endogenous creation of new opportunities that lead to the establish-
ment of competitive advantages. This process requires discovery of the cost structure of an
economy in order to identify which of the types of goods and services that already exist
in world markets can be produced in a domestic economy at low cost (Rodrik 2004). The
state plays a central coordinating role in this discovery process and often represents a lead
agent in economic development efforts. Because economic development is an endogenous
process, the state provides social capital, coordinates initiatives and public–private part-
nerships, fosters synergies, and promotes the introduction of new combinations that create
Schumpeterian rents (Reinert 2007).
and Nelson 1994). This becomes a problem if the trajectory being followed (or the paradigm
itself) is inferior or suboptimal to what could be achieved with technologies that transgress
the paradigm (or with a different paradigm).
Perez (2002) expanded the notion of technological paradigm to techno-economic para-
digm in order to account for the non-technological forces (economic and social institutions)
that characterize certain periods of capitalist history and affect both the economic and social
systems. Her theory of techno-economic paradigm shifts is a historical perspective on the
long waves of development that accompany technological revolutions.
A techno-economic paradigm is, then, a best-practice model made up of a set of all-pervasive
generic technological and organizational principles, which represent the most effective way of
applying a particular technological revolution and of using it for modernizing and rejuvenating
the whole of the economy. (Perez 2002, 15)
When a new technological revolution emerges, the socioeconomic system remains stuck
within the bounds of the previous paradigm. This renders market forces incapable of direct-
ing the system toward the new paradigm and stifles the modernizing and rejuvenating
potential of the new revolution. In other words, there are mismatches between elements of
the social and techno-economic systems (for example, social expectations, R&D routines,
tax regimes, labor regulations). In order to overcome these mismatches, it is necessary to
build new institutions that favor the diffusion of the new paradigm. In all previous techno-
logical revolutions, governments have led the process of institution-building that allowed
new techno-economic paradigms to replace the old ones. Perez (2002) specifically pointed
to the role that public policy plays in allowing the full deployment of technological revolu-
tions, such as the effect of suburbanization on the ability of the mass production revolution
to diffuse throughout the economy.
This stream of research on technological and techno-economic paradigms highlights the
importance of cognition when establishing the direction of technological change. Paradigms
are powerful enabling and constraining institutions that favor certain directions of tech-
no-economic development and obstruct others. In order to redirect techno-economic devel-
opment on a new, qualitatively different route, a paradigm shift is required that will avoid the
constant renewal of prevailing trajectories that occurs if market forces provide directionality
to the system. From this perspective, the state has a crucial role to play in terms of creating
a new vision that will coordinate cognitive efforts of different (public and private) agents
and direct their action to areas beyond the existing paradigm. Green innovation can be
understood as a redirection of the full deployment of the IT revolution (Mazzucato and Perez
2015). In order to effectively provide the direction of change, a vision must be created and
shared. Stirling (2008) correctly focused on the role of bottom-up participatory processes
to ensure directionality is taken seriously and shared amongst actors.
3.4. The entrepreneurial state: the state as lead risk-taker and investor in the
economy
Alternative approaches to innovation policy, such as those described above, have questioned
particular aspects of the economic dynamics embodied in neoclassical theory. However,
they have not questioned the underlying assumption of business being the only risk-taker.
The entrepreneurial state agenda has sought to challenge the notion of the entrepreneur
being embodied in private business, and policy-making being an activity outside of the
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 149
the economic landscape rather than just facilitating it. This section brings together key
concepts from the four heterodox frameworks reviewed above, drawing especially on the
empirical research conducted within these perspectives, in order to provide a new theoretical
conceptualization for guiding state action to tackle transformational change. The section
considers four new policy questions, which can help build a market-creating policy agenda
(Mazzucato 2015).
managing change (Kakabadse and Kakabadse 2002). More studies are needed to examine
the influence of outsourcing on the ability of public institutions to attract top-level talent
with the relevant knowledge and skills to manage transformative mission-oriented policies.
Without such talent and expertise, it is nearly impossible for the state to fulfill its role of
coordinating and providing direction to private actors when formulating and implementing
policies that address societal challenges. In order to promote transformation of the economy,
by shaping and creating technologies, sectors, and markets, the state must organize itself
so that it has the intelligence (policy capacity) to think big and formulate bold policies.
If the state is essential to the process of transformative technological and socioeconomic
change, it is also essential to understand the appropriate structure of public organizations.
Innovation is subject to extreme uncertainty, which creates the need for both patience
(“patient long-term capital”, Mazzucato 2013b) and the ability to experiment and explore
the underlying landscape (Rodrik 2004). Therefore, a crucial element in organizing the
state for its market-creating role is building its absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal
1990), a concept that has hitherto been restricted to private organizations. This absorptive
capacity will enable public agencies to learn in a process of investment, discovery, and
experimentation, and see policy as process (Hirschman 1967).
A key concern should be to establish skills/resources, capabilities, and structures that
can increase the chances that a public organization will be effective, both at learning and at
establishing symbiotic partnerships with the private sector, and ultimately succeed in imple-
menting mission-oriented and transformative policies. Public and private organizations
must re-rethink their roles when working together. Public–private partnerships have often
limited the public part in de-risking the private part. This ignores the capabilities and chal-
lenges involved in public sector risk-taking. De-risking assumes a conservative strategy that
minimizes the risks of picking losing projects, but does not necessarily maximize the prob-
ability of picking winners, which requires the adoption of a portfolio approach for public
investments (Rodrik 2013). In such an approach, the success of a few projects can cover
the losses from many projects, and the public organization in question also learns from its
loss-making investments (Mazzucato 2013a). Here, the matching between failures and fixes
is less important than having an institutional structure that ensures that winning policies
provide enough rewards to cover the losses, and that losses are used as lessons to improve
and renew future policies. Research on the developmental state (Block and Keller 2011) sug-
gests that these goals are best achieved not through heavy top-down policies, but through
a decentralized structure in which the organization(s) involved remain nimble, innovative,
and dynamic from within (Breznitz and Ornston 2013). This strand of thinking can benefit
from looking at the ways in which public–private partnerships were created when seeking
the joint creation of new products and services, including vaccines (Chataway et al. 2007).
the intrinsically dynamic character of economic development and the static tools used to
evaluate the role of the public policy in the process.
Failure to allow for the possibility that government can transform and create new land-
scapes that did not previously exist will affect the ability to measure such impact. This is
evident in innovation and also for public services (Crouch 2016). This situation then leads
to accusations of government crowding out business investment, which implies that the
areas that government moves into could have been areas for business investment. Such
claims are best defended through a crowding in argument, which relies on showing how
government investments create a larger national output pie (hence higher savings for private
investment to dip into). Indeed, as shown by Engel, Rothgang, and Eckl (2016, this issue),
public investments in R&D often crowd in further R&D investments by business.
However, a crowding in argument cannot provide a full explanation. It does not account
for the fact that businesses are frequently risk-averse and unwilling or unable to transform
existing landscapes or create new ones. Without indicators for such transformative action,
the static toolbox affects the government’s ability to determine whether it is simply operating
in existing spaces or making new things happen that would not have happened anyway (its
“additionality”). This often leads to investments that are overly narrow or directed within the
confines of the boundaries set by the business practices of the prevailing techno-economic
paradigm (Abraham 2010).
Therefore, it is crucial to develop a new toolbox and indicators for evaluating and measur-
ing the degree to which state investments open up and transform sectoral and technological
landscapes, rather than tinkering with existing ones. The indicators must take into account
the underlying risk and uncertainty absorbed in transforming such landscapes.
resource capacity of the economy; and voters will be more willing to accept the (inevitable)
failures if they see that those are compensated by important successes.
The public sector can use a number of return-generating mechanisms for its investments,
including retaining equity or royalties, retaining a golden share of the IPR, using income-con-
tingent loans, or capping the prices (which the tax payer pays) of those products that ema-
nate, as drugs do, from public funds (Angell, 2005; Mazzucato 2013a). Before exploring the
details of each mechanism, however, it is crucial for the policy framework to even allow the
question to be asked. In a market-shaping framework, does government have the right to
retain equity more than in a market failure framework? Are taxes currently bringing back
enough return to government budgets to fund high-risk investments that will probably fail?
5. Conclusion
This paper has considered the limitations of the market failure framework that continues to
guide innovation policy. It has argued that putting innovation at the center of growth policy
requires an emphasis on shaping and creating markets, rather than just fixing them and
that an alternative framework must also go beyond fixing system failures. To guide a mar-
ket-creating view, the paper has considered insights from alternative (heterodox) literatures
on the role of the state into producing structural change and transformation. Four critical
issues must be considered when building such a framework: (1) the direction of change
promoted by policy; (2) the nature of (public and private) organizations that can welcome
the underlying uncertainty and discovery process; (3) the evaluation of mission-oriented
and market-creation policies; and (4) the ways in which both risks and rewards can be shared
so that smart growth can also result in inclusive growth.
Considering the need for government policy to transform, be catalytic, and create and
shape markets rather just fix them helps reframe the key questions of economic policy from
static ones that deal with crowding out and picking winners to more dynamic ones that help
form the types of public–private interactions that can create new innovation and industrial
landscapes. The point is not to prescribe specific technologies, but to provide directions of
change around which bottom-up solutions can then experiment. As Stirling (2014, 2) put it:
The more demanding the innovation challenges like poverty, ill health or environmental dam-
age, the greater becomes the importance of effective policy. This is not a question of “picking
winners” – an uncertainty-shrouded dilemma which is anyhow equally shared between public,
private and third sectors. Instead, it is about engaging widely across society, in order to build
the most fruitful conditions for deciding what ‘winning’ even means.
While identifying key societal challenges is straightforward – climate change, aging,
resource security, housing, urbanization, etc. – translating challenges into concrete mis-
sions will require the involvement of an array of stakeholders concerned with sectors and
socio-technical fields affected by the challenge itself. Therefore, defining the direction of
investments should be based on sound diagnosis of each challenge by the state together
with other stakeholders.
Acknowledgements
Comments from Caetano Penna and an anonymous referee from the SPRU working paper series are
greatly appreciated. All errors remain the author’s.
154 M. MAZZUCATO
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.
Funding
The author acknowledges funding from a research grant funded by European Community’s H2020-
Euro-Society-2014 call on 'Overcoming the crisis: new ideas, strategies and governance structures
for Europe’ ” (ISIG grant no. 649186).
References
Abbate, J. 1999. Inventing the Internet. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Abraham, J. 2010. “Pharmaceuticalization of Society in Context: Theoretical, Empirical and Health
Dimensions.” Sociology 44 (4): 603–622.
Amsden, A. H. 2001. The Rise of “the Rest”. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Arrow, K. 1951. An Extension of the Basic Theorems of Classical Welfare Economics. Paper presented
at the Second Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Berkeley.
Block, F. L. 2008. “Swimming against the Current: The Rise of a Hidden Developmental State in the
United States”. Politics and Society 36 (2, June): 169–206.
Block, F. L., and M. R. Keller. 2011. State of Innovation: The U.S. Government’s Role in Technology
Development. Boulder, CO: Paradigm.
Breznitz, D., and D. Ornston. 2013. “The Revolutionary Power of Peripheral Agencies: Explaining
Radical Policy Innovation in Finland and Israel.” Comparative Political Studies 46 (10): 1219–1245.
Brown, R. 2016. “Mission Impossible? The Role of Universities in Peripheral Regional Innovative
Systems” by Ross Brown. Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Buchanan, J. M. 2003. “Public Choice: The Origins and Development of a Research Program.”
Champions of Freedom 31: 13–32.
Chataway, J., S. Brusoni, E. Cacciatori, R. Hanlin, and L. Orsenigo. 2007. “The International AIDS
Vaccine Initiative (IAVI) in a Changing Landscape of Vaccine Development: A Public/Private
Partnership as Knowledge Broker and Integrator.” The European Journal of Development Research
19 (1): 100–117.
Cohen, W. M., and D. A. Levinthal. 1990. “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and
Innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1): 128–152.
Crouch, Co. 2016. Rethinking Capitalism, edited by M. Jacobs and M. Mazzucato. London: Wiley
(forthcoming).
Dosi, G. 1982. “Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories.” Research Policy 11 (3):
147–162.
Dosi, G., and D. Lovallo. 1998. “Rational Entrepreneurs or Optimistic Martyrs? Some Considerations
on Technological Regimes, Corporate Entries, and the Evolutionary Role of Decision Biases.” In
Foresights and Oversights in Technological Change, edited by R. Garud, P. Nayyar, and Z. Shapiro,
41–68. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dosi, G., and R. R. Nelson. 1994. “An Introduction to Evolutionary Theories in Economics.” Journal
of Evolutionary Economics 4 (3): 153–172.
Engel, D., M. Rothgang, and V. Eckl. 2016. “The design of innovation policy and its effects on private
R&D.” Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Evans, P. B. 1995. Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation (Vol. 25). Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Flanagan, K., and E. Uyarra. 2016. “Innovation policy analysis, policy complexity and the scope for
successful policy action in an evolutionary world.” Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Foray, D., P. A. David, and B. Hall. 2009. “Smart Specialization: The Concept.” In Knowledge for Growth.
Prospects for Science, Technology and Innovation. Selected papers from Research Commissioner
Janez Potočnik’s Expert Group, 20.
INDUSTRY AND INNOVATION 155
Foray, D., D. Mowery, and R. R. Nelson. 2012. “Public R&D and Social Challenges: What Lessons
from Mission R&D Programs?” Research Policy 41 (10): 1697–1702.
Freeman, C. 1995. “The ‘National System of Innovation’ in Historical Perspective.” Cambridge Journal
of Economics 19 (1): 5–24.
Freeman, C., and L. Soete. [1974] 1997. The Economics of Industrial Innovation. 3rd ed. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Hirschman, A. O. 1967. Development Projects Observed. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kakabadse, A., and N. Kakabadse. 2002. “Trends in Outsourcing.” European Management Journal
20 (2): 189–198.
Keller, M. R., and F. Block. 2013. “Explaining the Transformation in the US Innovation System: The
Impact of a Small Government Program.” Socio-Economic Review 11 (4): 629–656.
Lazonick, W., and O. Tulum. 2011. “US Biopharmaceutical Finance and the Sustainability of the
Biotech Business Model.” Research Policy 40 (9): 1170–1187.
Lundvall, B. A. 1992. National Innovation System: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive
Learning. London: Pinter.
Martin, B. R. 2016. “R&D Policy Instruments – a Critical Review of What We Do and Don’t Know.”
Industry and Innovation (this issue).
Mazzoleni, R., and R. R. Nelson. 1998. “The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: A
Contribution to the Current Debate.” Research Policy 27 (3): 273–284.
Mazzucato, M. 2013a. The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking the Public Vs. Private Myth in Risk and
Innovation. London: Anthem Press.
Mazzucato, M. 2013b. “Financing Innovation: Creative Destruction Vs. Destructive Creation.”
Industrial and Corporate Change 22 (4): 851–867.
Mazzucato, M. 2013c. “Debunking the Market Mechanism: Organisations, Innovation and Inequality
– A Response to John Kay.” Political Quarterly 84 (4): 444–447.
Mazzucato, M. 2015. “Innovation Systems: From Fixing Market Failures to Creating Markets.”
Intereconomics 50 (3): 120–155.
Mazzucato, M., and C. C. R. Penna. 2014. “Beyond Market Failures: State Investment Banks and the
‘Mission-Oriented’ Finance for Innovation.” SPRU Working Paper Series 21.
Mazzucato, M., and C. C. R. Penna, eds. 2015. Mission-Oriented Finance for Innovation: New Ideas
for Investment-Led Growth. London: Pickering & Chatto ; Rowman & Littlefield.
Mazzucato, M., and C. Perez. 2015. “Innovation as Growth Policy,” in The Triple Challenge: Europe in
a New Age, edited by J. Fagerberg, S. Laestadius, and B. Martin. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mazzucato, M., and R. Wray. 2015. “Financing the Capital Development of the Economy: A Keynes–
Schumpeter–Minsky Synthesis.” Levy Institute Working Paper No. 837.
Motoyama, Y., R. Appelbaum, and R. Parker. 2011. “The National Nanotechnology Initiative: Federal
Support for Science and Technology, or Hidden Industrial Policy?” Technology in Society 33 (1–2):
109–118.
Mowery, D. C. 2010. “Military R&D and Innovation.” In Handbook of the Economics of Innovation
(Vol. 2), edited by B. H. Hall, and N. Rosenberg, 1219–1256. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Mowery, D. C., R. R. Nelson, and B. R. Martin. 2010. “Technology Policy and Global Warming: Why
New Policy Models Are Needed (or Why Putting New Wine in Old Bottles Won’t Work).” Research
Policy 39 (8): 1011–1023.
Nelson, R. R. (1977). The moon and the ghetto. New York: Norton.
Nelson, R. R., and S. G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA:
Belknap Press.
O’Riain, S. 2004. The Politics of High Tech Growth. Boston, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Perez, C. 2002. Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. Cheltenham: Edgar Elgar.
Polanyi, K. [1944] 2001. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.
(2nd Beacon Paperback ed.). Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Reinert, E. S. 2007. How Rich Countries Got Rich and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor. London:
Constable.
Rodrik, D. 2004. “Industrial Policy for the Twenty-First Century.” John F. Kennedy School of
Government Working Paper Series rwp04–047.
156 M. MAZZUCATO